Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m. EDT
June 17, 2022
Monetary Policy rePort
June 17, 2022
Letter of transmittaL
B  G  
F R S
Washington, D.C., June 17, 2022
T P   S
T S   H  R
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report pursuant to
section 2B of the Federal Reserve Act.
Sincerely,
Jerome H. Powell, Chair
Statement on Longer-run goaLS and monetary PoLicy Strategy
Adopted effective January24, 2012; as reafrmed effective January25, 2022
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is rmly committed to fullling its statutory mandate from
the Congress of promoting maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates. The
Committee seeks to explain its monetary policy decisions to the public as clearly as possible. Such clarity
facilitates well-informed decisionmaking by households and businesses, reduces economic and nancial
uncertainty, increases the eectiveness of monetary policy, and enhances transparency and accountability,
which are essential in a democratic society.
Employment, ination, and long-term interest rates uctuate over time in response to economic and nancial
disturbances. Monetary policy plays an important role in stabilizing the economy in response to these
disturbances. The Committee’s primary means of adjusting the stance of monetary policy is through changes
in the target range for the federal funds rate. The Committee judges that the level of the federal funds rate
consistent with maximum employment and price stability over the longer run has declined relative to its
historical average. Therefore, the federal funds rate is likely to be constrained by its eective lower bound
more frequently than in the past. Owing in part to the proximity of interest rates to the eective lower bound,
the Committee judges that downward risks to employment and ination have increased. The Committee is
prepared to use its full range of tools to achieve its maximum employment and price stability goals.
The maximum level of employment is a broad-based and inclusive goal that is not directly measurable
and changes over time owing largely to nonmonetary factors that aect the structure and dynamics of the
labor market. Consequently, it would not be appropriate to specify a xed goal for employment; rather, the
Committee’s policy decisions must be informed by assessments of the shortfalls of employment from its
maximum level, recognizing that such assessments are necessarily uncertain and subject to revision. The
Committee considers a wide range of indicators in making these assessments.
The ination rate over the longer run is primarily determined by monetary policy, and hence the Committee
has the ability to specify a longer-run goal for ination. The Committee rearms its judgment that ination
at the rate of 2percent, as measured by the annual change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with the Federal Reserve’s statutory mandate. The
Committee judges that longer-term ination expectations that are well anchored at 2percent foster price
stability and moderate long-term interest rates and enhance the Committee’s ability to promote maximum
employment in the face of signicant economic disturbances. In order to anchor longer-term ination
expectations at this level, the Committee seeks to achieve ination that averages 2percent over time, and
therefore judges that, following periods when ination has been running persistently below 2percent,
appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to achieve ination moderately above 2percent for some time.
Monetary policy actions tend to inuence economic activity, employment, and prices with a lag. In setting
monetary policy, the Committee seeks over time to mitigate shortfalls of employment from the Committee’s
assessment of its maximum level and deviations of ination from its longer-run goal. Moreover, sustainably
achieving maximum employment and price stability depends on a stable nancial system. Therefore, the
Committee’s policy decisions reect its longer-run goals, its medium-term outlook, and its assessments of
the balance of risks, including risks to the nancial system that could impede the attainment of the
Committee’s goals.
The Committee’s employment and ination objectives are generally complementary. However, under
circumstances in which the Committee judges that the objectives are not complementary, it takes into account
the employment shortfalls and ination deviations and the potentially dierent time horizons over which
employment and ination are projected to return to levels judged consistent with its mandate.
The Committee intends to review these principles and to make adjustments as appropriate at its annual
organizational meeting each January, and to undertake roughly every 5years a thorough public review of its
monetary policy strategy, tools, and communication practices.
Contents
note: This report reects information that was publicly available as of 4 p.m. EDT on June15, 2022.
Unless otherwise stated, the time series in the gures extend through, for daily data, June14, 2022; for
monthly data, May2022; and, for quarterly data, 2022:Q1. In bar charts, except as noted, the change for a
given period is measured to its nal quarter from the nal quarter of the preceding period.
For gures 23, 36, and 42, note that the S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index, the S&P 500 Index, and the Dow Jones Bank Index are
products of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC and/or its afliates and have been licensed for use by the Board. Copyright © 2022 S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, a
division of S&P Global, and/or its afliates. All rights reserved. Redistribution, reproduction, and/or photocopying in whole or in part are prohibited without
written permission of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC. For more information on any of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC’s indices, please visit www.spdji.com.
S&P
®
is a registered trademark of Standard & Poor’s Financial Services LLC, and Dow Jones
®
is a registered trademark of Dow Jones Trademark Holdings
LLC. Neither S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark Holdings LLC, their afliates, nor their third-party licensors make any representation or
warranty, express or implied, as to the ability of any index to accurately represent the asset class or market sector that it purports to represent, and neither
S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark Holdings LLC, their afliates, nor their third-party licensors shall have any liability for any errors,
omissions, or interruptions of any index or the data included therein.
Summary .................................................................1
Recent Economic and Financial Developments ................................... 1
Monetary Policy
........................................................... 3
Special Topics
............................................................. 3
Part 1: Recent Economic and Financial Developments .....................5
Domestic Developments. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
Financial Developments
.................................................... 27
International Developments
................................................. 35
Part 2: Monetary Policy ..................................................43
Part 3: Summary of Economic Projections
................................51
Abbreviations ............................................................69
List of Boxes
Developments in Global Supply Chains ......................................... 8
Developments in Employment and Earnings across Groups
......................... 14
Developments Related to Financial Stability
..................................... 31
Global Ination
.......................................................... 37
Monetary Policy in Foreign Economies
......................................... 39
Monetary Policy Rules in the Current Environment
................................ 46
Developments in the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet and Money Markets
.............. 49
Forecast Uncertainty
....................................................... 66
1
summary
In the rst part of the year, ination remained
well above the Federal Open Market
Committee’s (FOMC) longer-run objective
of 2percent, with some ination measures
rising to their highest levels in more than
40years. These price pressures reect supply
and demand imbalances, higher energy and
food prices, and broader price pressures,
including those resulting from an extremely
tight labor market. In the labor market,
demand has remained strong, and supply
has increased only modestly. As a result, the
unemployment rate fell noticeably below the
median of FOMC participants’ estimates of
its longer-run normal level, and nominal wages
continued to rise rapidly. Although overall
economic activity edged down in the rst
quarter, household spending and business xed
investment remained strong. The most recent
indicators suggest that private xed investment
may be moderating, but consumer spending
remains strong.
In response to sustained inationary pressures
and a strong labor market, the FOMC has
been adjusting its policies and communications
since last fall. At its March meeting, the
FOMC raised the target range for the federal
funds rate o the eective lower bound to ¼ to
½percent. The Committee continued to raise
the target range in May and June, bringing
it to 1½ to 1¾percent following the June
meeting, and indicated that ongoing increases
are likely to be appropriate. The Committee
ceased net asset purchases in early March and
began reducing its securities holdings in June.
The Committee is acutely aware that high
ination imposes signicant hardship,
especially on those least able to meet the
higher costs of essentials. The Committee’s
commitment to restoring price stability—
which is necessary for sustaining a strong labor
market—is unconditional.
Recent Economic and Financial
Developments
Ination. Consumer price ination, as
measured by the 12-month change in the
price index for personal consumption
expenditures (PCE), rose from 5.8percent
in December2021 to 6.3percent in April, its
highest level since the early 1980s and well
above the FOMC’s objective of 2percent.
This increase was driven by an acceleration of
retail food and energy prices, reecting further
increases in commodity prices due to Russia’s
invasion of Ukraine. The 12-month measure
of ination that excludes the volatile food and
energy categories (so-called core ination)
rose initially and then fell back to 4.9percent
in April, unchanged from last December.
Three-month measures of core ination have
softened since December but remain far
above levels consistent with price stability.
Measures of near-term ination expectations
continued to rise markedly, while longer-term
expectations moved up by less.
The labor market. Demand for labor continued
to outstrip available supply across many parts
of the economy, and nominal wages continued
to increase at a robust pace. While labor
demand remained very strong, labor supply
increased only modestly. As a result, the labor
market tightened further between December
and May, with job gains averaging 488,000per
month and the unemployment rate falling
from 3.9percent to 3.6percent—just above the
bottom of its range over the past 50years.
Economic activity. Real gross domestic
product (GDP) is reported to have surged at a
6.9percent annual rate in the fourth quarter of
2021 and then to have declined at a 1.5percent
annual rate in the rst quarter. The large
swings in growth rates reected uctuations
in the volatile expenditure categories of net
2 SUMMARY
exports and inventory investment. Abstracting
from these volatile components, growth in
private domestic nal demand (consumer
spending plus residential and business xed
investment—a measure that tends to be more
stable and better reects the strength of
overall economic activity) was strong in the
rst quarter, supported by some unwinding
of supply bottlenecks and a further reopening
of the economy. The most recent indicators
suggest that private xed investment may be
moderating, but consumer spending remains
strong. As a result, real GDP appears on track
to rise moderately in the second quarter.
Financial conditions. Financial conditions have
tightened signicantly this year. The expected
path of the federal funds rate over the next few
years shifted up substantially, and yields on
nominal Treasury securities across maturities
have risen considerably since late February
amid sustained inationary pressures and
associated expectations for further monetary
policy tightening. Equity prices were volatile
and declined sharply, on net, while corporate
bond yields increased substantially and spreads
increased notably, partly reecting some
concerns about the future corporate credit
outlook. Mortgage rates also rose sharply. In
turn, tighter nancial conditions may have
begun to weigh on some nancing activity. On
the business side, nonnancial corporate bond
issuance was solid in the rst quarter but slowed
somewhat in April and May, with speculative-
grade bond issuance being particularly
weak. That said, the growth of bank loans to
businesses picked up, and business credit quality
has remained strong thus far. For households,
mortgage originations declined materially.
Nevertheless, mortgage credit remained
broadly available for a wide range of potential
borrowers. For other consumer loans (such as
auto loans and credit cards), credit standards
eased somewhat further or changed little, and
credit outstanding grew briskly.
Financial stability. Despite experiencing
a series of adverse shocks—higher-than-
expected ination, the ongoing supply
disruptions related to COVID-19, and Russia’s
invasion of Ukraine—the nancial system
has been resilient, though portions of the
commodities markets temporarily experienced
elevated levels of stress. The drop in equity
prices and rising bond spreads suggest that
valuation pressures in corporate securities
markets have eased some from their previously
elevated levels, but real estate prices have
risen further this year. While business and
household debt has been growing solidly, the
ratio of credit to GDP has decreased to near
pre-pandemic levels and most indicators of
credit quality remained robust, suggesting that
vulnerabilities from nonnancial leverage are
moderate. Large bank capital ratios dipped
in the rst quarter, but overall leverage in the
nancial sector appears moderate and little
changed this year. Recent strains experienced
in markets for stablecoins—digital assets that
aim to maintain a stable value relative to a
national currency or other reference assets—
and other digital assets have highlighted the
structural fragilities in that rapidly growing
sector. A few signs of funding pressures
emerged amid the geopolitical tensions,
particularly in commodities markets. However,
broad funding markets proved resilient,
and with direct exposures of U.S. nancial
institutions to Russia and Ukraine being small,
nancial spillovers have been limited to date.
International developments. Economic
activity has continued to recover in many
foreign economies, albeit with new signicant
headwinds from Russia’s invasion of Ukraine
and COVID lockdowns in China. These
headwinds have, on net, pushed commodity
prices higher, worsened supply disruptions, and
lowered household and business condence,
thus damping the rebound in foreign economic
activity. As in the United States, consumer
price ination abroad is high and has
continued to rise in many economies, boosted
by higher energy, food, and other commodity
prices as well by supply chain constraints. In
response, many foreign central banks have
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 3
raised policy rates, and some have started to
reduce the size of their balancesheets.
Foreign nancial conditions have tightened
notably since the beginning of the year, in part
reecting the tightening in foreign monetary
policy and concerns about persistently high
ination. Sovereign bond yields in many
advanced foreign economies rose. Foreign
risky asset prices declined, also driven by
downside risks to the growth outlook amid
the lockdowns in China and Russia’s invasion
of Ukraine. The trade-weighted value of the
dollar appreciated notably.
Monetary Policy
In response to signicant ongoing ination
pressures and the tightening labor market, the
Committee has been adjusting its policies and
communications since last fall. The Committee
wound down net purchases of securities and
began reducing those securities holdings more
rapidly than expected, and also initiated a swift
increase in interest rates. Adjustments to both
interest rates and the balance sheet are playing
a role in rming the stance of monetary policy
in support of the Committee’s maximum-
employment and price-stability goals.
Interest rate policy. In March, after holding
the federal funds rate near zero since the
onset of the pandemic, the FOMC raised the
target range for that rate to ¼ to ½percent.
The Committee raised the target range again
in May and June, bringing it to the current
range of 1½ to 1¾percent, and conveyed
its anticipation that ongoing increases in the
target range will be appropriate.
Balance sheet policy. The Federal Reserve
began reducing its monthly net asset purchases
last November and accelerated the reductions
in December, bringing net purchases to an
end in early March. In January, the FOMC
issued a set of principles regarding its planned
approach for signicantly reducing the size of
the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. Consistent
with those principles, the Committee
announced in May its specic plans for
signicantly reducing its securities holdings
and that these reductions would begin on
June1.
1
The Committee acutely recognizes the
signicant hardship caused by elevated
ination, especially on those least able to meet
the higher costs of essentials. The Committee
is strongly committed to restoring price
stability, which is necessary for sustaining a
strong labor market.
Special Topics
Labor market disparities. The labor market
recovery over the past year and a half has
been robust and widespread as the labor
market eects of the pandemic have eased,
with particularly strong improvement among
groups that had suered the most. As a result,
employment and earnings of nearly all major
demographic groups are near or above their
levels before the pandemic, and employment
rates are again near multidecade highs.
However, there remain notable dierences in
employment and earnings across groups that
predate the pandemic.
Developments in global supply chains. Supply
chain bottlenecks remain a major impediment
for domestic and foreign rms. While U.S.
manufacturers have been recording solid
output growth for more than a year, order
backlogs and delivery times remain high, and
producer prices have risen rapidly. Further
risks to global supply chains abound. In
China, COVID-19 lockdowns drove the largest
monthly declines in industrial production there
since early 2020 while also disrupting internal
and international freight transportation. In
addition, the war in Ukraine continues to put
1. See the May4, 2022, press release regarding the
Plans for Reducing the Size of the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet, available at https://www.federalreserve.
gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20220504b.htm.
4 SUMMARY
upward pressure on energy and food prices
and has raised the risk of disruption in the
supply of inputs to some manufacturing
industries.
Monetary policy rules. Simple monetary policy
rules, which relate a policy interest rate to a
small number of other economic variables,
can provide useful guidance to policymakers.
Many simple policy rules prescribed strongly
negative values for the federal funds rate
during the pandemic-driven recession.
With ination running well in excess of the
Committee’s 2percent longer-run objective, a
strong U.S. economy, and tight labor market
conditions, the simple monetary policy rules
considered here call for raising the target range
for the federal funds rate signicantly.
Global ination. Ination abroad rose rapidly
over the past year, reecting soaring food and
commodity prices, pandemic-related supply
disruptions, and demand imbalances between
goods and services. The price pressures have
been amplied by the war in Ukraine and
COVID-19 lockdowns in China. Although
the recent ination surge was concentrated in
volatile components, such as food and energy,
price increases have broadened to core goods
and services.
Global monetary policy. With ination
rising sharply across the globe, many central
banks have tightened monetary policy.
Policy tightening started last year as some
emerging market central banks, particularly
those in Latin America, were concerned that
sharp increases in ination could become
entrenched in ination expectations. Since
fall 2021, many central banks in the advanced
foreign economies have also started tightening
monetary policy or are expected to do so soon,
and several central banks that had expanded
their balance sheets over the past two years are
now allowing them to shrink.
Developments in the Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet. Following the conclusion of net asset
purchases, the balance sheet remained stable
at around $9trillion. Alongside the removal of
policy accommodation—through actual and
expected increases in the policy rate—plans
for shrinking the size of the balance sheet
were announced in May and were initiated
in June. Despite the size of the balance sheet
remaining steady, reserve balances fell, in
large part because of increasingly elevated
take-up at the overnight reverse repurchase
agreement (ONRRP) facility, which reached a
record high of $2.2trillion. In an environment
of ample liquidity, limited Treasury bill
supply, and low repurchase agreement rates,
the ONRRP facility continued to serve its
intended purpose of helping to provide a oor
under short-term interest rates and to support
eective implementation of monetary policy.
5
Domestic Developments
Ination continued to run high . . .
After surging 5.8percent over 2021—the
largest increase since 1981—the price index
for personal consumption expenditures (PCE)
continued to post notable increases so far
this year, and the change over the 12 months
ending in April stood at 6.3percent (gure1).
This pace is well above the FOMC’s longer-run
objective of 2percent.
. . . reecting further large increases in
food and energy prices . . .
Grocery prices increased at a very rapid pace
of 10percent over the 12months ending in
April, more than 4percentage points faster
than over the 12 months ending in December
and the highest reading since 1981 (gure2).
Food commodity prices (such as wheat and
corn), which had already increased last year,
have risen further since Russia’s invasion of
Ukraine. At the same time, high fuel costs,
supply chain bottlenecks, and high wage
growth have also pushed up processing,
packaging, and transportation costs for food.
The PCE price index for energy increased
30percent over the 12 months ending in April,
Part 1
reCent eConomiC and finanCiaL deveLoPments
Excluding food
and energy
Trimmed mean
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
Percent change from year earlier
202220212020201920182017201620152014
1. Change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures
Monthly
Total
NOTE: The data extend through April 2022.
S
OURCE: For trimmed mean, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; for all
else, Bureau of Economic Analysis; all via Haver Analytics.
2. Personal consumption expenditures price indexes
Food and
beverages
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Percent change from year earlier
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
20222021202020192018
Percent change from year earlier
Energy
NOTE: The data are monthly and extend through April 2022.
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Services
ex energy
and housing
Goods ex food,
beverages, and
energy
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
Percent change from year earlier
20222021202020192018
Monthly
Housing
services
NOTE: The data extend through April 2022.
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
6 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
12-month percent change
202220212020201920182017201620152014
5. Nonfuel import price index
Monthly
N
OTE
: The data extend through April 2022.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
about the same pace as over the 12months
ending in December. Large increases in crude
oil and natural gas commodity prices have
boosted consumer prices for gasoline and
natural gas.
. . . which, in turn, partly reected rising
prices of commodities and imports
Because of Russia’s invasion of Ukraine, oil
prices rose sharply in early March, reaching
eight-year highs (gure3). Prices remain
elevated and volatile, boosted by a European
Union embargo of Russian oil imports
but weighed down at times by concerns
about global economic growth. In addition,
producers in other countries are struggling to
ramp up oil production.
Nonfuel commodity prices also surged after
the invasion, with large increases in the
prices of both agricultural commodities and
industrial metals (gure4). Although the price
of industrial metals has declined recently,
agricultural prices remain elevated. Ukraine
and Russia are notable exporters of wheat,
Russia is a major exporter of fertilizer, and
higher energy prices are spilling over into the
agricultural sector. Export restrictions and
unfavorable weather conditions in several
countries have also boosted agricultural prices.
(See the box “Developments in Global Supply
Chains.”)
With commodity prices surging and foreign
goods prices on the rise, import prices
increased signicantly (gure5).
Excluding food and energy prices,
monthly ination readings have softened
since the turn of the year but remain
far above levels consistent with price
stability
Supply chain issues, hiring diculties, and
other capacity constraints have prevented
the supply of products from rising quickly
enough to satisfy continued strong demand,
resulting in large price increases for many
goods and services over the past year. After
excluding consumer food and energy prices,
Brent spot price
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
Dollars per barrel
2007 2010 2013 2016 2019 2022
3. Spot and futures prices for crude oil
Weekly
24-month-ahead
futures contracts
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend through
June 10, 2022.
S
OURCE
: ICE Brent Futures via Bloomberg.
Agriculture
and livestock
60
80
100
120
140
160
180
Week ending January 3, 2014 = 100
2014 2015 2016 2017 20182019 2020 2021 2022
4. Spot prices for commodities
Weekly
Industrial metals
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend throug
h
June 10, 2022.
S
OURCE: For industrial metals, S&P GSCI Industrial Metals Index
Spot; for agriculture and livestock, S&P GSCI Agriculture & Livestock
Spot Index; both via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 7
the 12-month measure of core PCE ination
rose initially and then fell back to 4.9percent
in April, unchanged from December.
That said, monthly core ination readings
have softened noticeably since the start of the
year, with the three-month measure of core
PCE ination falling from an annual rate of
6.0percent last December to 4.0percent in
April. In particular, ination stepped down for
durable goods, likely reecting some easing in
supply constraints.
Nevertheless, the recent ination readings have
been mixed, remain far above levels consistent
with price stability, and are far from conclusive
evidence on the direction of ination. Unlike
durable goods price ination, core services
ination has not declined signicantly.
Housing service prices continue to rise at a
brisk pace, and increased demand for travel is
markedly pushing up ination rates for lodging
and airfares. More generally, rapid growth of
labor costs is putting upward pressure on the
prices of all labor-intensive services.
Measures of near-term ination
expectations continued to rise markedly,
while longer-term expectations moved up
by less
The rst half of 2022 saw further increases in
expectations of ination for the year ahead in
surveys of both consumers and professional
forecasters (gure6). In the University of
Michigan Surveys of Consumers, the median
value for ination expectations over the
next year jumped to 5.4percent in March,
its highest level since November1981, and
has moved sideways since then. A portion
of the upward movement so far this year
likely reects the war in Ukraine and the
accompanying increases in the prices of
commodities, especially those related to energy
and food.
Longer-term expectations, which are more
likely to inuence actual ination over time,
moved up by less and remained above pre-
pandemic levels. The Michigan survey’s
median ination expectation for the next
CIE, projected onto
10-year SPF
Michigan survey,
next 12 months
SPF, 10 years ahead
CIE, projected onto
Michigan, next 5 to 10 years
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
Percent
202220202018201620142012201020082006
6. Measures of ination expectations
Michigan survey,
next 5 to 10 years
N
OTE: The Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) data are
quarterly, begin in 2007:Q1, and extend through 2022:Q2. The data for
the Index of Common Ination Expectations (CIE) and the Michigan
survey are monthly and extend through June 2022; the June data for the
Michigan survey and the CIE are preliminary.
S
OURCE: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers;
Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, SPF; Federal Reserve Board, CIE;
Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
8 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
mixed for bottlenecks in the transportation of goods.
The number of ships waiting for berths at West Coast
ports has declined noticeably, as port throughput has
remained high, although manufacturers continue to cite
logistics and transportation constraints as reasons for
loweroutput.
Bottlenecks in global production and transportation
remain a major impediment for both domestic and
foreign  rms. Russia’s invasion of Ukraine and the
widespread COVID-19 lockdowns in China have
exacerbated strains in global supply networks and
have led to greater uncertainty about the timing of
improvement in supply conditions.
Despite this turbulence in the global supply
network, U.S. manufacturers have been recording
solid output growth for more than a year. There have
been gains in domestic motor vehicle production,
as the supply of semiconductors has recovered
somewhat ( gure A). In addition, survey results
suggest shorter supplier delivery times and lower order
backlogs relative to their late 2021 levels ( gure B).
Notwithstanding these improvements, backlogs and
delivery times for the sector remain elevated, and light
vehicle assemblies are still a bit below pre-pandemic
levels, with low dealer inventories continuing to
constrain sales. For some materials that had previously
been in short supply—such as lumber and steel—
prices have declined from notable highs. Even so,
the overall producer price index for manufacturing
in April was more than 18percent above its year-
earlier level ( gureC). Progress has been similarly
Developments in Global Supply Chains
(continued)
70
80
90
100
110
January 2020 = 100
Feb. Apr. Jun. Aug. Oct. Dec. Feb.Apr.
2021 2022
A. U.S. light motor vehicle production
Monthly
N
OTE
: The data extend through April 2022. The data are a
djusted
using Federal Reserve Board seasonal factors.
S
OURCE
: Ward’s Automotive Group, AutoInfoBank and
Intelligence
Data
Query; Chrysler Group LLC, North American Production Data
;
General
Motors Corporation, GM Motor Vehicle Assembly Productio
n
Data.
Order backlogs
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Diusion index
2022201720122007
B. Suppliers’ delivery times and order backlogs
Monthly
Delivery
times
N
OTE: Values greater than 50 indicate that more respondents reported
longer delivery times or order backlogs relative to a month earlier than
reported shorter delivery times or order backlogs.
S
OURCE:Institute for Supply Management, ISM Manufacturing Report
on Business.
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
Percent change from year earlier
202220212020201920182017
C. Producer price index for manufacturing
Monthly
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 9
Risks to supply chain conditions abound, including
those arising from COVID-19 lockdowns in China
beginning in mid-March and the ongoing war in
Ukraine.
1
Committed to their zero-COVID strategy,
Chinese authorities ratcheted up restrictions quickly
in the face of rising cases of the Omicron variant,
which included a complete lockdown of Shanghai.
The containment strategy managed to reduce case
counts, allowing authorities to begin relaxing some
citywide restrictions in late April. The lockdowns drove
the largest monthly declines in Chinese activity since
early 2020, with industrial production dropping about
13percent between February and April ( gure D)
before recovering some in May. With severely disrupted
domestic logistics, supplier delivery times increased
sharply in April and continued increasing in May, but
not as strongly ( gure E). Chinese international trade
was also hit, contracting in the three months before
April ( gure F). As Chinese production continues to
recover, the associated rebound in trade  ows may
further strain international transportation networks.
1. The July1 expiration of the contract between
dockworkers and West Coast port operators poses an
additional risk for shipping-related disruption.
Retail sales
16
12
8
4
+
_
0
4
8
12
Percent change
Jan. Mar. May July Sept. Nov.Jan.Mar.May
2021 2022
Monthly
Industrial production
N
OTE
: Industrial production data are adjusted using Federal Reserv
seasonal factors. Retail sales data are seasonally adjusted by
S
OURCE
:National Bureau of Statistics of China via Haver Analytics
50
55
60
65
70
Diusion index
2022202120202019
E. China’s purchasing managers index: Supplier delivery times
Monthly
N
OTE
: The series is seasonally adjusted. Values greater than 50
indicate
that more respondents reported longer delivery times relative to
a month earlier than reported shorter delivery times.
S
OURCE: Caixin; S&P Global; both via Haver Analytics.
Imports
50
+
_
0
50
100
150
200
Percent change
Jan. Mar. May July Sept. Nov. Jan. Mar. May
2021 2022
F. Nominal trade growth in China
Monthly
Exports
N
OTE
: All series are seasonally adjusted at an annual rate using
Federal Reserve Board seasonal factors. The data are 3-month moving
averages.
S
OURCE
: General Administration of Customs, China, via Haver
Analytics.
The invasion of Ukraine by Russia is causing
economic hardship. For instance, the con ict has
disrupted global commodity markets in which Ukraine
and Russia account for signi cant shares of global
exports. Notably, energy prices have soared, as
(continued on next page)
10 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
increasing geopolitical tensions have put the supply
of Russian oil and gas to Europe at risk. Indeed,
Russian energy exports have already been falling amid
embargos on Russian oil, self-sanctioning by some
companies, transportation dif culties, and Russia’s
decision to halt gas deliveries to several European
countries. The prices of several nonfuel commodities
that are vital inputs to some manufacturing industries
jumped in the early days of the con ict, including
neon gas (an input in semiconductor chip production),
palladium (an input in semiconductors and catalytic
converters), nickel (an input in electric vehicles’
batteries), and platinum. However, prices have
since retreated to near pre-invasion levels as major
disruptions have failed to materialize thus far. Finally,
blocked shipping routes in the Black Sea have severed
the region’s agricultural exports, disrupting global food
markets. As a result, prices of corn, wheat, sun ower
oil, and fertilizer have climbed to record-high levels,
raising concerns of food insecurity across the globe.
Further aggravating the situation, a number of countries
introduced export bans on some food commodities to
contain rising domestic food prices.
Thus far, the war appears to have had more limited
effects on other aspects of global supply chains.
The effect on supplier delivery times across Europe
has been muted, suggesting that the repercussions
for manufacturers in the region have been relatively
modest so far outside of the shifts in commodity prices
Developments in Global Supply Chains (continued)
Euro area
40
45
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
Diusion index
2022202120202019
G. Purchasing managers index: Supplier delivery times
Monthly
United Kingdom
N
OTE: The series are seasonally adjusted. Values greater than 50
indicate
that more respondents reported longer delivery times relative
to
a month earlier than reported shorter delivery times.
SOURCE: For the United Kingdom, S&P Global and the
Chartered
Institute of Procurement & Supply; for the euro area, S&P Global; all via
Haver Analytics.
( gure G). The global transportation system has also
proved mostly resilient to the war, with signs of further
strain in only a couple of sectors. Oil tanker charter
rates spiked, boosted by a rise in demand as oil started
to move to new markets, while truck transportation
prices rose further, re ecting higher diesel fuel costs.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 11
5to 10years rose to 3.3percent in the June
preliminary reading. If conrmed, this reading
would be near the top of the range from the
past 25years. Nevertheless, it remains well
below the corresponding measure of 1-year-
ahead ination expectations. In the second-
quarter Survey of Professional Forecasters, the
median expectation for 10-year PCE ination
edged up to 2.4percent, reecting noticeable
upward revisions to expected ination this
year and next but little change thereafter; the
median expectation for 6 to 10years ahead
held steady at 2percent.
Market-based measures of longer-term
ination compensation, which are based
on nancial instruments linked to ination,
are sending a similar message. A measure
of consumer price index (CPI) ination
compensation 5 to 10years ahead implied
by Treasury Ination-Protected Securities is
little changed (on balance) since late 2021 and
remains well below the corresponding measure
of ination compensation over the next 5years
(gure7).
The Index of Common Ination Expectations,
which is produced by Federal Reserve Board
sta and synthesizes information from a large
range of near-term as well as longer-term
expectation measures, edged up in the rst half
of this year and now stands at the high end of
the range from the past 20years.
The labor market continued to tighten
Payroll employment expanded an average of
488,000 per month in the rst ve months of
the year (gure8). Payroll gains so far this year
have been broad based across industries, with
the leisure and hospitality sector continuing to
see the largest gains as people continued their
return to activities that had been cut back by
the pandemic.
The increase in payrolls was accompanied
by further declines in the unemployment
rate, which fell 0.3percentage point over the
rst ve months of the year to 3.6percent
in May, just above the bottom of its range
125
130
135
140
145
150
155
Millions of jobs
202220202018201620142012201020082006
8. Nonfarm payroll employment
Monthly
SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
5-year
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
Percent
2022202020182016201420122010
7. Ination compensation implied by Treasury
Ination-Protected Securities
Daily
5-to-10-year
N
OTE: The data are at a business-day frequency and are estimated
from smoothed nominal and ination-indexed Treasury yield curves.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board
sta calculations.
12 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
over the past 50years (gure9). The
decline in the unemployment rate has been
fairly broad based across age, educational
attainment, gender, and ethnic and racial
groups (gure10). These declines have
helped employment of nearly all major
demographic groups recover to near or above
their levels before the pandemic. (See the box
“Developments in Employment and Earnings
across Groups.”)
While labor demand remained very
strong, labor supply increased only
modestly and stayed below
pre-pandemic levels
Demand for labor continued to be very
strong in the rst half of the year. At the
end of April, there were 11.4million job
openings—60percent above pre-pandemic
levels and down a bit from the all-time high
recorded in March.
Meanwhile, the supply of labor rose only
gradually and remained below pre-pandemic
levels. The labor force participation rate
(LFPR), which measures the share of people
Black or African American
Asian
Hispanic or Latino
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Percent
202220202018201620142012201020082006
10. Unemployment rate, by race and ethnicity
Monthly
White
N
OTE: Unemployment rate measures total unemployed as a percentage of the labor force. Persons whose ethnicity is identied as Hispanic or Latino
may be of any race. Small sample sizes preclude reliable estimates for Native Americans and other groups for which monthly data are not reported by
the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
Percent
202220202018201620142012201020082006
9. Civilian unemployment rate
Monthly
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 13
either working or actively seeking work,
edged up just 0.1percentage point in the
rst ve months of the year—following a
0.4percentage point improvement last year—
to 62.3percent in May (gure11).
2
Despite these improvements, the LFPR
remains 1.1percentage points below its
February2020 level.
3
About one-half of
this decline in the participation rate was
to be expected even in the absence of the
pandemic, as additional members of the
large baby-boom generation have reached
retirement age. In addition, several pandemic-
related factors appear to be continuing to
hold down the participation rate, including
a pandemic-induced surge in retirements
(beyond that implied by the aging of the
baby boomers) and, to a diminishing extent,
increased caregiving responsibilities and
some continuing concerns about contracting
COVID-19.
In addition to subdued participation, a second
factor constraining the size of the labor force
has been a marked slowing in population
growth since the start of the pandemic. Over
2020 and 2021, the working-age (16 and over)
population grew by 0.4percent per year on
average—notably less than the 0.9percent
2. The Bureau of Labor Statistics incorporated new
population estimates beginning with the January2022
employment report. This development resulted in a
one-time jump in the estimate of the aggregate LFPR
of about 0.3percentage point due to a change in the
age distribution of the population. Accordingly, the
0.4percentage point increase in the published measure
from December to May overstates the improvement in
the LFPR by about 0.3percentage point.
3. This shortfall in the LFPR corresponds to
a shortfall in the labor force of about 2.8million
persons. (This calculation holds the LFPR constant
at its February2020 level and assumes population
growth equal to the actual growth observed since
February2020.)
Employment-to-
population ratio
50
52
54
56
58
60
62
64
66
68
Percent
202220202018201620142012201020082006
11. Labor force participation rate and
employment-to-population ratio
Monthly
Labor force participation rate
N
OTE: The labor force participation rate and the employment-
to-population ratio are percentages of the population aged 16 and over.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
14 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Employment for Blacks and Hispanics not only
declined by more than that for whites and Asians
early in the pandemic, but also recovered more
quickly since the end of last year ( gure A, upper-
right panel). In addition, men and women with high
school degrees or less saw larger declines and a faster
recovery ( gureA, lower-left panel). Similarly, gaps in
employment between prime-age mothers and non-
mothers that widened through 2020 have essentially
closed ( gureA, lower-right panel). By April2022,
employment for all of those groups was near or above
its pre-pandemiclevel.
These differences in the timing of the employment
recovery across different demographic groups partly
re ect the evolution of the pandemic’s effect on the
labor market. For instance, social-distancing restrictions
and concerns about contracting or spreading
COVID-19 had likely inhibited employment in in-
person services. As these restrictions and concerns
have waned, employment of groups more commonly
employed in in-person services, such as those with less
education and some minority groups, has recovered
quickly.
3
Further, the closing of many schools and
childcare facilities for the 2020–21 school year due
to elevated levels of COVID cases likely held back
the employment recovery of parents, as many families
faced uncertainties about the consistent availability
of in-person education for school-age children and
childcare for younger children. The effects appear to
have been particularly acute for mothers, especially
Black and Hispanic mothers, as well as those with less
3. Before the pandemic, Blacks and Hispanics were
less likely to be employed in jobs that could be performed
remotely, and women and Blacks were more likely to be
employed in occupations that involved greater face-to-face
interactions; for example, see Laura Montenovo, Xuan Jiang,
Felipe Lozano Rojas, Ian M. Schmutte, Kosali I. Simon,
Bruce A. Weinberg, and Coady Wing (2020), “Determinants
of Disparities in COVID-19 Job Losses,” NBER Working
Paper Series 27132 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research, May; revised June2021), https://www.
nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w27132/w27132.pdf.
Other research shows that even after accounting for
workers’ job characteristics, Hispanic and nonwhite workers
experienced a higher rate of job loss relative to other
workers; see Guido Matias Cortes and Eliza Forsythe (2021),
“The Heterogeneous Labor Market Impacts of the Covid-19
Pandemic,” unpublished paper, August, http://publish.illinois.
edu/elizaforsythe/files/2021/08/Cortes_Forsythe_Covid-demo_
revision_8_1_2021.pdf.
Labor market gains have been robust over the
past year and a half as the economy continues to
recover from the effects of the pandemic. Historically,
economic downturns have tended to exacerbate
long-standing differences in employment and earnings
across demographic groups, especially for minorities
and for those with less education, and this pattern was
especially true early on in the pandemic. However,
as pandemic-related factors have eased and the labor
market has recovered, groups with larger employment
declines early in the pandemic have had especially
large increases lately. Now employment and real
earnings of nearly all major demographic groups are
near or above their levels before the pandemic, and
employment rates are again near multidecade highs.
Different age groups have had very different
employment experiences over the course of the
pandemic.
1
Early in the pandemic, the employment-to-
population (EPOP) ratio for people aged 16 to 24 not
only declined by much more than that for people of
prime age (25 to 54) and those aged 55 to 64, but also
recovered much more quickly (see gure A, upper-
left panel).
2
Conversely, employment recovered more
slowly for prime-age people throughout 2020 and
nearly all of 2021. But in late 2021 and early 2022,
the prime-age EPOP rose quickly, such that now all
three of these age groups’ EPOP ratios have essentially
recovered to their pre-pandemic levels. The EPOP ratio
for those aged 65 and over, however, remains about
1percentage point below its pre-pandemic level—a
level it has maintained through much of the pandemic.
The lower EPOP ratio for that group is entirely
attributable to a lower labor force participation rate,
which in turn largely re ects an increase in retirements
since the onset of the pandemic.
A closer look at the prime-age group shows that
there has been considerable heterogeneity in the pace
of the employment recovery across race and ethnicity,
educational attainment, and parental status.
1. The January2022 employment report incorporates
population controls that showed that the working-age
population was both larger and younger over the past
decade than the Census Bureau had previously estimated.
Those population controls had meaningful effects on the
aggregate EPOP ratio, but much smaller effects at the levels of
disaggregation examined in this discussion.
2. This discussion de nes the pre-pandemic baseline
EPOP ratio for each group as that group’s average EPOP ratio
over 2019.
Developments in Employment and Earnings across Groups
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 15
year, these childcare burdens likely eased, allowing
many parents to reenter the workforce.
See Joshua Montes, Christopher Smith, and Isabel Leigh
(2021), “Caregiving for Children and Parental Labor Force
Participation during the Pandemic,” FEDS Notes (Washington:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
November5), https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/
feds-notes/caregiving-for-children-and-parental-labor-force-
participation-during-the-pandemic-20211105.htm.
A. Changes in employment-to-population ratio compared with the 2019 average ratio, by group
16 to 24
Black or
African American
65+
Asian
55 to 64
Hispanic or Latino
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
Percentage points
2022202120202019
Age group
Monthly
25 to 54
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
Percentage points
2022202120202019
Race and ethnicity: Prime age
Monthly
White
Men, college
or more
Parents
Women, high school
or less
Women, college
or more
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
Percentage points
2022202120202019
Educational attainment: Prime age
Monthly
Men, high school
or less
N
OTE
: Prime age is 25 to 54. The age groups 16 to 24 and prime age show seasonally adjusted data published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, whereas
all other groups’ data are seasonally adjusted by the Federal Reserve Board sta.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations from Current Population Survey microdata.
12
10
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
Percentage points
2022202120202019
Parental status: Prime-age women
Monthly
Nonparents
(continued on next page)
education.
4
However, with schools having generally
provided in-person education for the 2021–22 school
4. The increase in the share of mothers of school-age
children who reported being out of the labor force due to
caregiving closely tracked the degree to which schools were
fully closed to in-person learning over the 2020–21 school
year, and districts that serve more Blacks and Hispanics
were less likely to provide fully in-person education during
the 2020–21 school year, which may account for some
of the larger and more persistent declines in labor force
attachmentfor Black and Hispanic mothers over this period.
16 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
time real earnings for women versus men is slightly
smaller in 2022:Q1 than it was in 2019, as is the gap
in median real earnings between Black and white full-
time workers.
6
6. Some of a group’s earnings growth relative to 2019 may
re ect lingering pandemic-related compositional shifts in the
group’s full-time workers. Additionally, real earnings growth
accounts for aggregate in ation, but some demographic
groups may be disproportionately exposed to in ation due
to differences in groups’ consumption patterns—implying
lower real earnings growth for groups with greater exposure to
in ation.
Although the gaps in employment outcomes
across groups that widened during the pandemic have
diminished, the considerable gaps that existed before
the pandemic remain. For example, the EPOP ratio for
whites of prime age remains more than 3percentage
points above those for prime-age Black and Hispanic
people; the EPOP ratio of college-educated, prime-age
people is about 15percentage points higher than that
of prime-age people with high school degrees or less;
and the EPOP ratio for prime-age mothers is about
5percentage points below that of non-mothers—all
similar in size to the gaps that existed before the
pandemic.
The broad-based nature of the labor market recovery
is also apparent in workers’ earnings, which have
grown rapidly as employment surged in 2021 and early
2022. As of 2022:Q1, the median full-time worker’s
usual weekly earnings had grown 12.3percent relative
to pre-pandemic levels—implying real earnings growth
of 3.1percent ( gure B).
5
Although this earnings growth
has been widespread, it has been largest for women,
minorities, young workers, and workers with less than a
high school education. The growth in earnings for some
demographic groups has been suf ciently robust to
shrink some pre-pandemic disparities in real earnings
between groups. For instance, the gap in median full-
5. Just as with the change in the EPOP ratio, each group’s
pre-pandemic baseline is de ned as the group’s average
median usual weekly earnings in 2019. The reported growth in
real usual weekly earnings de ates nominal earnings growth
by total PCE (personal consumption expenditures) in ation.
If, instead, the CPI were used to de ate nominal earnings,
then reported real earnings growth since 2019 would be
2percentage points lower—but even when using the CPI to
de ate nominal earnings, real earnings have risen for most
groups since 2019.
B. Growth in median full-time usual weekly earnings
from 2019 to 2022:Q1
Percent change relative to 2019 average
NominalReal (PCE)
0246810121416
Hispanic or Latino
Asian
Black or African American
White
65+
55–64
25–54
16–24
Bachelor’s or more
Some college
High school
Less than high school
Women
Men
Overall
N
OTE: The percent change as of 2022:Q1 is relative to the 2019 average of
the
median usual weekly earnings for full-time workers in each group. Real
earnings growth deates the nominal earnings growth by the average growth in
the
personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index as of 2022:Q1
relative
to its 2019 average level. The overall earnings, as well as those for men
and
women, use seasonally adjusted data, but the other groups’ earnings are
not seasonally adjusted. The key identies bars in order from left to right.
S
OURCE
: For median usual weekly earnings, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for
the PCE price index, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Developments in Employment and Earnings across Groups (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 17
average rate over the previous ve years.
4
The slowing in population growth over
2020–21 was due to both a sharp decline in
net immigration and a spike in COVID-related
deaths.
5
Had the population increased over
2020–21 at the same rate as over the previous
ve years, the labor force would have been
about 1¾million larger as of the second
quarter of this year.
6
As a result, labor markets remained
extremely tight . . .
Reecting very strong demand for workers
alongside still-subdued supply, a wide range
of indicators have continued to point to an
extremely tight labor market despite the fact
that the level of payroll employment in May
remained about 820,000 below the level in
February2020.
7
The number of total available
jobs, measured by total employment plus
posted job openings, continued to far exceed
the number of available workers, measured by
the size of the labor force.
8
The gap was
4. Population forecasts just before the onset of the
pandemic also projected faster population growth
for 2021–22 than has been realized. For example, the
Congressional Budget Oce projected 0.8percent
growth per year in 2021–22 in its January2020 budget
and economic projections; see Congressional Budget
Oce (2020), The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2020
to 2030 (Washington: CBO, January), https://www.cbo.
gov/publication/56020. Before 2015, population growth
was even higher. For example, the average growth rate in
the working-age population between 1980 and 2014 was
1.2percent per year.
5. The eect of COVID-related deaths on the labor
force, however, was relatively smaller, because these
deaths have been concentrated among older individuals,
who tend to have low LFPRs.
6. This calculation uses the actual LFPR in May2022
and multiplies it by the level of the population that would
have been realized in that month had population growth
over 2020–21 been the same as the growth observed over
2015–19.
7. After adjusting for population growth since the
beginning of the pandemic, the shortfall in payrolls
relative to their pre-pandemic level was about 2.3million
in May.
8. The labor force includes all people aged 16
and older who are classied as either employed or
unemployed.
18 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
about 5½million at the end of April, near the
highest level on record.
9
The share of workers
quitting jobs each month, an indicator of the
availability of attractive job prospects, was
2.9percent at the end of April, near the all-
time high reported in November (gure12).
Initial claims for unemployment benets
remain near the lowest levels observed in
the past 50years. Households’ and small
businesses’ perceptions of labor market
tightness were near or above the highest
levels observed in the history of these series.
And, nally, employers continued to report
widespread hiring diculties.
That said, some possible signs of modest
easing of labor market tightness have recently
appeared. For example, as noted in the next
section, some measures of wage growth appear
to have moderated. And in the June2022 Beige
Book, employers in some Federal Reserve
Districts reported some signs of modest
improvement in worker availability.
. . . and nominal wages continued to
increase at a robust pace
Reecting very tight labor market conditions,
nominal wages continued to rise at historically
rapid rates. For example, the employment
cost index (ECI) of total compensation rose
4.8percent over the 12 months ending in
March, well above 2.8percent from a year
earlier (gure13). The most recent readings
include a surge in bonuses, which may reect
the challenges of retaining and hiring workers.
In addition, wage growth as computed by
the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, which
tracks the median 12-month wage growth
of individuals responding to the Current
Population Survey, picked up markedly this
year and rose more than 6percent in May, well
above the 3to 4percent pace reported over the
previous few years.
9. Another usual indicator of the gap between
available jobs and available workers is the ratio of job
openings to unemployment. At the end of April, this
indicator showed that there were 1.9 job openings per
unemployed person.
Compensation per hour,
business sector
Atlanta Fed’s
Wage Growth Tracker
Employment cost index,
private sector
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
10
Percent change from year earlier
20222020201820162014
13. Measures of change in hourly compensation
Average hourly earnings,
private sector
N
OTE: Business-sector compensation is on a 4-quarter percent change
basis. For the private-sector employment cost index, change is over the
12 months ending in the last month of each quarter; for private-sector
average hourly earnings, the data are 12-month percent changes; for the
Atlanta Fed’s Wage Growth Tracker, the data are shown as a 3-month
moving average of the 12-month percent change.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta,
Wage Growth Tracker; all via Haver Analytics.
Vacancy-to-
unemployment ratio
0
.3
.6
.9
1.2
1.5
1.8
2.1
2.4
Ratio
.8
1.2
1.6
2.0
2.4
2.8
3.2
202220202018201620142012201020082006
12. Ratio of job openings to job seekers and quits rate
Percent of employment
Nonfarm quits rate
N
OTE: The data are monthly and extend through April 2022. The
vacancy-to-unemployment ratio data are the ratio of job openings to
unemployed.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Job Openings and Labor
Turnover Survey.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 19
That said, there are some signs that
nominal wage growth may be leveling o or
moderating. The growth of wages and salaries
as measured by the ECI moderated from
5.6percent at an annual rate in the second half
of last year to 5.2percent early this year. And
even as payroll employment continued to grow
rapidly and the unemployment rate continued
to fall, the three-month change in average
hourly earnings declined from about 6percent
at an annual rate late last year to 4.5percent
in May, with the moderation in earnings
growth particularly notable for employees in
the sectors that experienced especially strong
wage growth last year, such as leisure and
hospitality.
Following a period of solid growth, labor
productivity softened
The extent to which sizable wage gains
raise rms’ unit costs and act as a source of
ination pressure depends importantly on the
pace of productivity growth. Considerable
uncertainty remains around the ultimate
eects of the pandemic on productivity.
From 2019 through 2021, productivity growth
in the business sector picked up (albeit by
less than compensation growth), averaging
about 2¼percent at an annual rate—about
1percentage point faster than the average pace
of growth over the previous decade (gure14).
Some of this pickup in productivity growth
might reect persistent factors. For example,
the pandemic resulted in a high rate of new
business formation, the widespread adoption
of remote work technology, and a wave of
labor-saving investments.
The latest reading, however, showed a
decline in business-sector productivity in the
rst quarter of this year. While quarterly
productivity data are notoriously volatile, this
decline nevertheless highlights the possibility
that some of the earlier productivity gains
could prove transitory, perhaps reecting
worker eort initially surging in response to
employment shortages and hiring diculties
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
Percent, annual rate
14. Change in business-sector output per hour
1949–
73
1974–
95
1996–
2003
2004–
08
2009–
18
2019–
21
2022
N
OTE
: Changes are measured from Q4 of the year
immediately
preceding the period through Q4 of the nal year of the period, except
2022 changes, which are calculated from 2021:Q1 to 2022:Q1.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
20 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
and then subsequently returning to more
normal levels.
10
If the gap between wage
growth and productivity growth remains
comparably wide in the future, the result
will be signicant upward pressure on rms’
laborcosts.
Gross domestic product declined in the
rst quarter of 2022 after having surged
in the fourth quarter of 2021 . . .
Real gross domestic product (GDP) is reported
to have surged at a 6.9percent annual rate in
the fourth quarter of 2021—and then to have
declined at a 1.5percent annual rate in the rst
quarter—because of uctuations in net exports
and inventory investment (gure15). These
two categories of expenditures are volatile even
in normal times, and they have been even more
so in recent quarters. Some improvement in
supply chain conditions late last year appears
to have enabled rms to rebuild depleted
inventories; inventory investment surged in
the fourth quarter and then moderated to a
still-elevated pace in the rst quarter, thereby
weighing on GDP growth. Other measures
of activity, including employment, industrial
production, and gross domestic income,
indicate continued growth in the rst quarter.
. . . while growth in consumer spending
and business investment was solid in the
rst quarter
After abstracting from these volatile
components, growth in private domestic nal
demand (consumer spending plus residential
and business xed investment—a measure
that tends to be more stable and better reects
the strength of overall economic activity)
was solid in the rst quarter, supported by
some unwinding of supply bottlenecks and a
further reopening of the economy. The most
recent spending data and other indicators
suggest that private xed investment may be
10. The November2021 Beige Book reported that
many employers were planning to increase hiring because
of concerns that their current workforce was being
overworked.
17.0
17.5
18.0
18.5
19.0
19.5
20.0
Trillions of chained 2012 dollars
20222021202020192018201720162015
15. Real gross domestic product
Quarterly
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 21
moderating, but consumer spending remains
strong and drag from inventory investment
and net exports may be dissipating. As a
result, private domestic nal demand and real
GDP appear on track to rise moderately in the
second quarter.
Real consumer spending growth
remained strong . . .
Real consumer spending—that is, spending
after adjusting for ination—continued to
grow briskly, supported by a partial unwinding
of supply bottlenecks and continued
normalization of spending patterns as the
pandemic fades. For example, spending
on motor vehicles grew markedly in the
rst quarter, reecting improvements in
both domestic and foreign production, and
spending on services (especially at restaurants)
grew briskly.
That said, consumer spending growth has
moderated from its very rapid pace from
early 2021 as scal support has declined
from historical highs, some households have
likely depleted excess savings accumulated
during the pandemic, and ination has eroded
households’ purchasing power.
The composition of spending remains more
tilted toward goods and away from services
than it was before the pandemic. Real goods
spending is still well above its trend, while
real spending on services remains below trend
(gure16). Nevertheless, the composition
continued to shift back toward services. While
goods spending was only modestly higher in
April compared with its average from late last
year, services spending rose signicantly.
. . . supported by high levels of wealth
Household wealth grew by roughly $30trillion
between late 2019 and late 2021 because of
rises in equity and house prices along with
the elevated rate of saving in 2020 and 2021
(gures17 and 18). Since the beginning of the
year, wealth has declined because of the drop
in equity prices. Nevertheless, wealth remains
0
4
8
12
16
20
24
28
32
36
PercentMonthly
202220202018201620142012201020082006
18. Personal saving rate
NOTE: The data extend through April 2022.
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Goods
6.5
7.0
7.5
8.0
8.5
9.0
9.5
Trillions of chained 2012 dollars
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
202220202018201620142012201020082006
16. Real personal consumption expenditures
Trillions of chained 2012 dollars
Services
N
OTE: The data are monthly and extend through April 2022.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
7.5
8.0
8.5
Ratio
202220202018201620142012201020082006
17. Wealth-to-income ratio
Quarterly
NOTE: The series is the ratio of household net worth to disposable
personal income.
S
OURCE: For net worth, Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release
Z.1, “Financial Accounts of the United States”; for income, Bureau of
Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
22 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
well above pre-pandemic levels, providing
continuing support for consumer spending.
Consumer nancing conditions were
generally accommodative, especially for
borrowers with stronger credit scores
Financing has been generally available to
support consumer spending. Following a
period of widespread reported easing last year,
standards on credit card loans eased somewhat
further in the rst quarter, whereas those on
auto and other consumer loans changed little.
Partly reecting higher credit card purchase
volumes, credit card balances grew rapidly in
recent months (gure19). Even so, many credit
card users still have ample unused credit. Auto
loans grew briskly during the rst quarter,
consistent with the concurrent rebound in
autosales.
Meanwhile, borrowing costs rose. However,
they remain below pre-pandemic levels for
credit cards and auto loans, partly reecting
strong consumer credit quality. Indeed,
delinquency rates on consumer loans remain
low relative to historical averages despite some
recent increases among nonprime borrowers.
Housing construction remained high but
may be moderating . . .
New single-family construction has remained
well above pre-pandemic levels. However,
new construction may be softening, with
single-family permits turning down some in
March and April (gure20). As in the past
year, still-tight supplies of materials, labor,
and other inputs may still be restraining new
construction. Also, builders have become
distinctly less optimistic about prospects for
housing sales, perhaps owing to the sharp rise
in mortgage rates (gure21).
. . . while home sales fell amid low
inventories and rising mortgage rates
Home sales stepped down substantially from
the very high levels prevailing late last year
and are now close to pre-pandemic levels
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
Percent
20222020201820162014
21. Mortgage rates
Weekly
N
OTE
: The data are contract rates on 30-year,xed-rate conventional
home mortgage commitments and extend through June 9, 2022.
S
OURCE
: Freddie Mac Primary Mortgage Market Survey.
Single-family
permits
Multifamily starts
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
2.0
Millions of units, annual rate
202220202018201620142012201020082006
20. Private housing starts and permits
Monthly
Single-family starts
N
OTE: The data extend through April 2022.
S
OURCE
: U.S. Census Bureau via Haver Analytics.
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
40
Billions of dollars, monthly rate
20222020201820162014201220102008
19. Consumer credit ows
Apr.
Q1
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release G.19,
Consumer
Credit.”
Student loans
Auto loans
Credit cards
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 23
(gure22). Some of this decline may have
reected further reductions in inventories
of existing homes to historically low levels
early in the year. In addition, the sharp
increases in mortgage rates may have begun to
moderate housing demand. Even so, nancing
conditions in the residential mortgage market
remained accommodative for borrowers who
met standard loan criteria, and the terms of
mortgage credit for households with lower
credit scores continued to ease toward pre-
pandemic levels. Listings, sales, and price data
suggest that so far, demand remains strong
relative to the pace at which homes are being
made available for sale. For example, the share
of homes o market within two weeks remains
elevated, and as of April, several measures of
national house prices were up about 20percent
from a year earlier, though less in real terms
(gure23).
Business xed investment rose strongly
in the rst quarter but may now be
moderating
Investment in equipment and intangibles
surged at a 12½percent annual rate in the
rst quarter (gure24). Investment demand
remained strong, as worker shortages and
high-capacity utilization in manufacturing
likely maintained strong incentives for rms
to automate production and boost capital
expenditures. In turn, strong investment
demand continued to boost equipment prices
in an environment of constrained supply,
but there have been initial signs that supply
constraints may have begun to ease. In
particular, since late last year, shipments of
capital goods have begun to catch up with
orders. The most recent indicators suggest that
the growth of investment in equipment and
intangibles will slow signicantly in the second
quarter, possibly reecting drag from tighter
nancial conditions.
Investment in nonresidential structures
declined moderately in the rst quarter after
falling more rapidly over the second half of
CoreLogic
price index
S&P/Case-Shiller
national index
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
130
2005:Q1 = 100
202220202018201620142012201020082006
23. Real prices of existing single-family houses
Quarterly
Zillow index
N
OTE: Series are deated by the personal consumption expenditures
price index.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics;
CoreLogic Home Price Index; Zillow, Inc., Real Estate Data;
S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index. The S&P/Case-Shiller
index is a product of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC and/or its aliates.
(For Dow Jones Indices licensing information, see the note on the
Contents page.)
Existing home sales
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
Millions, annual rate
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
202220202018201620142012201020082006
22. New and existing home sales
Millions, annual rate
New home sales
N
OTE: The data are monthly and extend through April 2022.
New
home sales include only single-family sales. Existing home sales include
single-family, condo, and co-op sales.
S
OURCE: For new home sales, U.S. Census Bureau; for existing home
sales, National Association of Realtors; all via Haver Analytics.
24 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
2021, and it appears on track to decline again
in the second quarter. Declines in spending on
nondrilling structures have been only partly
oset by rapid increases in drilling investment,
which reect the recent rise in energy prices.
Business nancing conditions tightened
somewhat but remained generally
accommodative
Credit remained available to most nonnancial
corporations, but nancing conditions
tightened somewhat, especially for lower-
rated rms. Gross nonnancial corporate
bond issuance was solid in the rst quarter
but slowed somewhat in April and May, with
speculative-grade bond issuance particularly
weak. Leveraged loan issuance also declined
notably in May, partly reecting weakening
demand from retail investors. The growth of
business loans at banks picked up from the
subdued pace of last year, reecting stronger
loan originations as well as a moderation in
loan forgiveness associated with the Paycheck
Protection Program.
Credit also remained broadly available to
small businesses. The share of small rms
reporting that it was more dicult to obtain
loans (compared with three months earlier)
remained low by historical standards. Loan
origination data through April were consistent
with credit availability being comparable
with pre-pandemic levels amid gradually
recovering demand for small business credit.
Most measures of loan performance remained
largely stable; through April, default and
delinquency rates remained below their pre-
pandemic levels.
The strong U.S. demand has partly been
met through a rapid rise in imports
Driven by the continued strength in domestic
economic activity, including still-strong
demand for goods consumption, U.S. imports
continued to grow at a rapid pace, surging well
above their pre-pandemic trend (gure25).
High levels of imported goods have kept
international logistics channels operating
Imports
1,500
1,750
2,000
2,250
2,500
2,750
3,000
3,250
3,500
3,750
4,000
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
20222020201820162014201220102008
25. Real imports and exports of goods
and services
Quarterly
Exports
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Structures
1,000
1,200
1,400
1,600
1,800
2,000
2,200
2,400
2,600
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
350
400
450
500
550
600
650
202220192016201320102007
24. Real business xed investment
Billions of chained 2012 dollars
Equipment and
intangible capital
N
OTE: Business xed investment is known asprivate nonresidential
xed investment” in the national income and product accounts. The data
are quarterly.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 25
under high pressure, which has continued to
impair the timely delivery of goods to U.S.
customers. Real goods exports have only
recovered to pre-pandemic levels. Real exports
and imports of services remain subdued,
reecting a slow recovery of international
travel. Given the recent strength of imports
relative to the milder recovery in exports, the
nominal trade decit widened further as a
share of GDP (gure26).
The support to economic activity
provided by federal scal actions
continued to diminish . . .
In response to the pandemic, the federal
government enacted scal policies to address
the economic consequences of the pandemic.
Because the boost to spending from these
policies ended last year, the eects on demand
are likely waning this year and weighing on
GDP growth.
. . . and, in turn, the budget decit has
fallen sharply from pandemic highs, and
the growth of federal debt has moderated
The Congressional Budget Oce estimates
that scal policies enacted since the start of
the pandemic will increase federal decits
roughly $5.4trillion by the end of scal
year2030, with the largest decit eects
having occurred in scal 2020 and 2021.
11
These policies, combined with the eects of
the automatic stabilizers—the reduction in tax
receipts and increase in transfers that occur
as a consequence of depressed economic
11. For more information, see Congressional Budget
Oce (2020), “The Budgetary Eects of Laws Enacted in
Response to the 2020 Coronavirus Pandemic, March and
April2020, June, https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2020-
06/56403-CBO-covid-legislation.pdf; Congressional
Budget Oce (2021), “The Budgetary Eects of Major
Laws Enacted in Response to the 2020–21 Coronavirus
Pandemic, December2020 and March2021, September,
https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2021-09/57343-
Pandemic.pdf; and Congressional Budget Oce
(2021), “Senate Amendment 2137 to H.R. 3684, the
Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act, as Proposed on
August1, 2021, August9, https://www.cbo.gov/system/
files/2021-08/hr3684_infrastructure.pdf.
Current account
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
+
_
0
Percent of nominal GDP
20222019201620132010200720042001
26. U.S. trade and current account balances
Quarterly
Trade
N
OTE: GDP is gross domestic product. Current account balance data
extend through 2021:Q4.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
26 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
activity—caused the federal decit to surge to
15percent of nominal GDP in scal 2020 and
remain elevated at 12½percent in scal 2021.
But with pandemic scal programs having
largely ended and receipts surging, the decit
has fallen sharply thus far in scal 2022 relative
to scal 2021 and, by the end of the scal year,
is expected to be close to the decits prevailing
just before the pandemic (gure27).
As a result of the scal support enacted during
the pandemic, federal debt held by the public
jumped to around 100percent of nominal
GDP in scal 2020—the highest debt-to-
GDP ratio since 1947 (gure28). But with
decits falling and economic growth having
rebounded, the debt-to-GDP ratio has since
receded slightly from its recent peak.
State and local government budget
positions are remarkably strong . . .
Federal policymakers provided a historic
level of scal support to state and local
governments during the pandemic, with
aid totaling about $1trillion. This aid has
more than covered pandemic-related budget
shortfalls in the aggregate. Moreover, following
the pandemic-induced slump, total state tax
collections—pushed up by the economic
expansion—rose appreciably in 2021 and
continued to grow rapidly in early 2022
(gure29). In turn, this recovery in revenues
has led some state governments to enact or
consider enacting tax cuts. At the local level,
property taxes have continued to rise apace,
and the typically long lags between changes
in the market value of real estate and changes
in tax collections suggest that property tax
revenues will rise quite substantially going
forward, given the rise in house prices.
. . . but hiring and construction outlays
have continued to lag
Despite the return to in-person schooling and
the strong scal position of state and local
governments, state and local government
payrolls continued to expand only modestly
in the rst half of 2022. Employment levels
Expenditures
14
16
18
20
22
24
26
28
30
32
Percent of nominal GDP
202220172012200720021997
Annual
27. Federal receipts and expenditures
Receipts
N
OTE: Through 2021, the receipts and expenditures data are on a
unied-budget basis and are for scal years (October to
September);
gross domestic product (GDP) is for the 4 quarters ending in Q3. For
2022, receipts and expenditures are for the 12 months ending in May;
GDP is the average of 2021:Q4 and 2022:Q1.
S
OURCE: Department of the Treasury, Financial Management Service;
Oce of Management and Budget and Bureau of Economic Analysis via
Haver Analytics.
Debt held by
the public
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
Percent of nominal GDP
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
28. Federal government debt and net interest outlays
Percent of nominal GDP
1902 1922 1942 1962 1982 2002 2022
Net interest outlays
on federal debt
N
OTE
: The data for net interest outlays are annual, begin in 1948, and
extend through 2021. Net interest outlays are the cost of servicing the
debt held by the public. Federal debt held by the public equals federal
debt less Treasury securities held in federal employee dened-benet
retirement accounts, evaluated at the end of the quarter. The data
for
federal debt are annual from 1901 to 1951 and quarterly thereafter. GDP
is gross domestic product.
S
OURCE: For GDP, Bureau of Economic Analysis; for federal debt,
Congressional Budget Oce and Federal Reserve Board, Statistical
Release Z.1, “Financial Accounts of the United States.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 27
have regained about 60percent of their sizable
pandemic losses, falling well short of the
recovery in private payrolls (gure30). One
reason for this disparity appears to be that
public-sector wages have not kept pace with
the rapid gains in the private sector, which may
be inhibiting the ability of these governments
to sta back up to pre-pandemic levels.
Meanwhile, real construction outlays by state
and local governments continued to decline
in the rst half of the year and are currently
about 15percent below pre-pandemic levels.
Financial Developments
The expected level of the federal funds
rate over the next few years shifted up
substantially
In March, May, and June, the FOMC raised
the target range for the federal funds rate a
total of 1½percentage points. The expected
path of the federal funds rate over the next few
years also shifted up substantially since late
February (gure31). Economic data releases
and FOMC communications were viewed
by market participants as implying tighter
monetary policy than previously expected.
Market-based measures suggest that investors
anticipate the federal funds rate to exceed
3.6percent by the end of this year, which is
about 2percentage points higher than the level
expected in late February. The same measures
suggest that the federal funds rate is expected
to peak at about 4percent in mid-2023 before
gradually declining to about 3.1percent by
the end of 2025, which is about 1.4percentage
points higher than the end-2025 rate expected
in late February.
Similarly, according to the results of the
Survey of Primary Dealers and the Survey of
Market Participants, both conducted by the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York in April,
the median of respondents’ projections for
18.0
18.5
19.0
19.5
20.0
20.5
Millions of jobs
202220202018201620142012201020082006
Monthly
30. State and local government payroll employment
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
Total state taxes
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
Percent change from year earlier
202220202018201620142012
29. State and local tax receipts
NOTE:State tax data are year-over-year percent changes of 12-month
moving averages, begin in June 2012, extend through April 2022, and are
aggregated over all states except Wyoming, for which data are not
available. Revenues from Washington, D.C., are also excluded. Data are
missing for March 2022 to April 2022 for New Mexico and Oregon and
April 2022 for Nevada, as these states have longer reporting lags than
others. Property tax data are year-over-year percent changes of 4-quarter
moving averages, begin in 2012:Q2, extend through 2021:Q4, and are
primarily collected by local governments.
S
OURCE: Monthly State Government Tax Revenue Data via Urban
Institute; U.S. Census Bureau, Quarterly Summary of State and Local
Government Tax Revenue.
Property taxes
28 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
the most likely path of the federal funds rate
shifted up signicantly since January.
12
Before late February, the expected path of
the federal funds rate had started to increase
notably in the third quarter of last year, in
anticipation of increases in the target range.
Consistent with the rise in the expected
path of the federal funds rate, yields on
Treasury securities and corporate bonds, as
well as mortgage rates, all started to increase
materially at a similar time. Meanwhile,
broad equity price indexes have declined
on net. Overall, these moves in asset prices
suggest tightening of nancial conditions even
before the initial increase in the target range
of the federal funds rate occurred in March
(gure32).
Yields on U.S. nominal Treasury securities
also rose considerably
Yields on nominal Treasury securities across
maturities have risen considerably since late
February (gure33). After a brief dip in
late February, following Russia’s invasion
of Ukraine, yields rose steadily amid higher
inationary pressures and associated
expectations for monetary policy tightening.
The increases in nominal Treasury yields
were primarily accounted for by rising
real yields. Uncertainty about longer-term
interest rates—as measured by the implied
volatility embedded in the prices of near-term
options on 10-year interest rate swaps—also
increased signicantly, reportedly reecting,
in part, an increase in uncertainty about the
policyoutlook.
Yields on other long-term debt increased
substantially
Across credit categories, corporate bond
yields have increased substantially and
12. The results of the Survey of Primary Dealers
and the Survey of Market Participants are available
on the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s website at
https://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/primarydealer_
survey_questions.html and https://www.newyorkfed.org/
markets/survey_market_participants, respectively.
10-year Treasury
Mortgage rate
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Percent
20222021202020192018201720162015
32. Financial market indicators
Daily
Investment-grade corporate
N
OTE
: Investment-grade corporate reects the eective yield of the
ICE Bank of America Merrill Lynch triple-B U.S. Corporate Index
(C0A4). The mortgage rate is contract rates on 30-year,xed-rate
conventional home mortgage commitments. Mortgage rate data extend
through June 9, 2022.
S
OURCE
: Department of the Treasury via Haver Analytics; Freddie
Mac Primary Mortgage Market Survey; ICE Data Indices, LLC,
used
with permission.
2-year
5-year
0
1
2
3
4
Percent
202220202018201620142012
33. Yields on nominal Treasury securities
Daily
10-year
S
OURCE
: Department of the Treasury via Haver Analytics.
June 14, 2022
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
Percent
20262025202420232022
31. Market-implied federal funds rate path
Quarterly
February 25, 2022
N
OTE
: The federal funds rate path is implied by quotes on overnight
index swaps—a derivative contract tied to the eective federal funds rate.
The implied path as of February 25, 2022, is compared with that as of
June 14, 2022. The path is estimated with a spline approach, assuming a
term premium of 0 basis points. The February 25, 2022, path extends
through 2026:Q1 and the June 14, 2022, path through 2026:Q2.
S
OURCE
: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 29
spreads over yields on comparable-maturity
Treasury securities have increased notably
since late February. Corporate bond yields
and spreads are somewhat above the
historical median values of their respective
historical distributions since the mid-1990s
(gure34). Municipal bond yields also
increased signicantly while spreads increased
somewhat since late February. Spreads on
municipal bonds are now moderately above
their historical medians. On net, corporate
bond spreads are moderately above their pre-
pandemic levels, and municipal bond spreads
are near levels prevailing shortly before the
pandemic. While the widening of corporate
bond spreads since late February appears
to partly reect a deterioration in market
expectations of future credit quality, corporate
and municipal credit quality thus far in 2022
have remained strong. So far this year, defaults
have been low, and upgrades of bond ratings
have outpaced downgrades in both markets.
Since late February, yields on agency
mortgage-backed securities (MBS)—an
important pricing factor for home mortgage
rates—increased signicantly, as longer-term
Treasury yields increased and spreads over
comparable-maturity Treasury securities
widened (gure35). MBS spreads increased as
market participants’ expectations of a gradual
reduction in the Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet shifted to a faster reduction.
Broad equity price indexes declined
sharply, on net, amid substantial volatility
Broad equity price indexes were volatile and
declined sharply, on net, amid sustained
ination pressures and expectations of
monetary policy tightening, as well as
heightened uncertainty regarding Russia’s
invasion of Ukraine and the economic outlook
(gure36). Bank stock prices also declined on
net. One-month option-implied volatility on
the S&P 500 index—the VIX—rose notably to
elevated levels in the days following Russia’s
invasion of Ukraine. The VIX trended down
for some time only to increase again and
Yield
0
50
100
150
200
250
Basis points
1
2
3
4
5
202220202018201620142012
35. Yield and spread on agency mortgage-backed
securities
Percent
Spread
N
OTE: The data are daily. Yield shown is for the uniform
mortgage-backed securities 30-year current coupon, the coupon rate at
which new mortgage-backed securities would be priced at par, or face,
value, for dates after May 31, 2019; for earlier dates, the yield shown is
for the Fannie Mae 30-year current coupon. Spread shown is to the
average of the 5-year and 10-year nominal Treasury yields.
S
OURCE: Department of the Treasury; J.P. Morgan. Courtesy of J.P
.
Morgan Chase & Co., Copyright 2022.
High-yield corporate
Municipal
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Percent
2010 2012 2014 2016201820202022
34. Corporate bond yields, by securities rating, and
municipal bond yield
Daily
Investment-grade corporate
N
OTE: Investment-grade corporate reects the eective yield of the
ICE Bank of America Merrill Lynch (BofAML) triple-B U.S.
Corporate
Index (C0A4). High-yield corporate reects the eective yield of the ICE
BofAML High Yield Index (H0A0). Municipal reects the yield to worst
of the ICE BofAML U.S. Municipal Securities Index (U0A0).
S
OURCE
: ICE Data Indices, LLC, used with permission.
30 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
remain elevated since late April amid a notable
deterioration in risk sentiment (gure37). (For
a discussion of nancial stability issues, see
the box “Developments Related to Financial
Stability.”)
Markets for Treasury securities, mortgage-
backed securities, corporate and
municipal bonds, and equities generally
functioned in an orderly way, but some
measures of liquidity deteriorated
Liquidity conditions in the market for
Treasury securities, which had deteriorated
somewhat since late 2021, in part as a result
of heightened interest rate risk, worsened
further in late February following Russia’s
invasion of Ukraine. Market depth—a gauge
of the ability to transact in large volumes at
quotes posted by market makers—for Treasury
securities fell and remains at historically low
levels. Bid-ask spreads increased somewhat.
However, trading volumes remained within
normal ranges, suggesting that market
functioning was not materially impaired.
The decreases in depth were the greatest for
bonds with shorter maturities because the
prices of those securities are more sensitive to
expectations for monetary policy over the near
term. The market for MBS has functioned
in an orderly way since late February, even
as some measures of liquidity conditions
deteriorated. Measures of market functioning
in corporate and municipal bond markets
indicated that the markets have remained
liquid and trading conditions have stayed
stable since late February without substantive
disruptions around the time of Russia’s
invasion of Ukraine. Transaction costs in the
corporate bond market and in the municipal
bond market have both picked up somewhat
since late February, and in the corporate bond
market, bid-ask spreads are modestly above
pre-pandemic levels. Transaction costs remain
fairly low by historical standards.. Liquidity
in equity markets has declined since late 2021
in part because of rising uncertainty about
the outlook for monetary policy as well as
Russia’s invasion of Ukraine and has remained
VIX
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Percent
2022202020182016201420122010
37. S&P 500 volatility
Daily
Expected volatility
N
OTE
: The VIX is a measure of implied volatility that represents the
expected annualized change in the S&P 500 index over the following
30 days. The expected volatility series shows a forecast of 1-month
realized volatility, using a heterogeneous autoregressive model based on
5-minute S&P 500 returns.
S
OURCE
: Cboe Volatility Index® (VIX®) via Bloomberg; Renitiv
DataScope; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
S&P 500 index
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
December 31, 2010 = 100
202220202018201620142012
36. Equity prices
Daily
Dow Jones bank index
S
OURCE: S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC via Bloomberg. (For Dow
Jones Indices licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 31
previously very elevated levels but were still above
their historical median. Corporate-to-Treasury spreads
widened but remained below their historical median.
Spreads on leveraged loans were little changed, and
leveraged loan issuance remained solid. House prices
continued to rise at a rapid pace that further outstripped
rent growth. Commercial real estate prices also rose
further, with some price indexes surpassing their
2006peaks.
The rapid growth of nominal GDP outpaced the
growth of total debt of non nancial businesses and
households. The ratio of the aggregate debt owed by
the private non nancial sector to nominal GDP further
declined to near pre-pandemic levels ( gure A). Net
leverage of large non nancial businesses held stable at
This discussion reviews vulnerabilities in the U.S.
nancial system. The framework used by the Federal
Reserve Board for assessing the resilience of the U.S.
nancial system focuses on  nancial vulnerabilities
in four broad areas: asset valuations, business and
household debt, leverage in the  nancial sector, and
funding risks. With in ation running higher than
expected, the invasion of Ukraine, and the pandemic’s
continued effects on supply chains and consumer
demand patterns, uncertainty about the economic
outlook increased, and prices of some  nancial assets
uctuated widely. Treasury yields increased markedly,
and valuation pressures in corporate securities markets
eased, but real estate prices have risen further this year
despite a rise in mortgage rates. While business and
household debt has been growing solidly, the ratio of
private non nancial credit to gross domestic product
(GDP) decreased to near pre-pandemic levels and most
indicators of credit quality remained robust. Large bank
capital ratios dipped in the  rst quarter, but overall
leverage in the  nancial sector appears moderate
and little changed this year. A few signs of funding
pressures emerged amid the escalation of geopolitical
tensions. However, broad funding markets proved
resilient, and with direct exposures of U.S.  nancial
institutions to Russia and Ukraine being small,  nancial
spillovers have been limited to date. Nevertheless, the
effect of high in ation, supply chain disruptions, and
the ongoing geopolitical tensions remain substantial
sources of uncertainty with the potential to further
stress the  nancial system.
Valuation measures based on current expectations
of cash  ows decreased in some markets but continued
to be high relative to historical norms. Re ecting a less
accommodative monetary policy stance associated
with elevated in ation and a tight labor market, yields
on Treasury securities increased markedly and reached
somewhat above their pre-pandemic levels. Broad
equity prices  uctuated widely and declined sharply.
Prices relative to earnings forecasts declined from
Developments Related to Financial Stability
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
Ratio
202220172012200720021997199219871982
A. Private nonnancial-sector credit-to-GDP ratio
Quarterly
NOTE: The shaded bars indicate periods of business recession
as
dened
by the National Bureau of Economic Research:
January
1980–July
1980, July 1981–November 1982, July 1990–March
1991,
March
2001–November 2001, December 2007–June 2009, and
February
2020–April 2020. GDP is gross domestic product.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1, “Financia
l
Accounts
of the United States”; Bureau of Economic Analysis, nationa
l
income and product accounts; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
(continued on next page)
32 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
(continued)
have been directly affected by the Russia–Ukraine
con ict, but loan exposures of large U.S. banks to
these  rms and borrowers in Ukraine and Russia are
small. However, several indirect channels—heightened
volatility in asset markets; new disruptions in payment,
clearing, or settlement systems; and interconnections
with large European banks—could adversely affect the
U.S. economy and  nancial system.
Funding risks at domestic banks and broker-
dealers are low, but structural vulnerabilities persist at
some money market funds (MMFs), bond funds, and
stablecoins. Banks relied only modestly on short-term
wholesale funding, and the share of high-quality liquid
assets at banks remained historically high. Assets
under management at prime and tax-exempt MMFs
have continued to decline, but these funds remain a
structural vulnerability due to their susceptibility to
runs. In December2021, the Securities and Exchange
Commission proposed reforms to MMFs, including
the adoption of swing pricing for certain fund types,
increased liquidity requirements, and other measures
meant to make them more resilient to redemptions. The
Russian invasion of Ukraine does not appear to have
left a material imprint on broader short-term funding
markets. Trading conditions in those markets have been
stable, issuance continued, and spreads remained well
below the levels reached in March2020. Although
depth in markets for Treasury securities and some
commodity and equity derivatives has been low by
historical standards, those markets have functioned
normally after the initial shock to the nickel market.
Elevated market volatility—particularly in commodity
markets—caused central counterparties (CCPs) to make
larger margin calls. To date, clearing members have
below pre-pandemic levels, supported by ample cash
holdings. Fueled by strong earnings and low borrowing
costs, the ratio of earnings to interest expenses for the
median  rm among public non nancial businesses rose
to its highest level in two decades, indicating that large
rms were better able to service debt. However, for
rms in industries hit hardest by the pandemic, leverage
remains elevated and interest coverage ratios are lower.
The  nancial position of many households continued to
improve. Household debt relative to nominal GDP as
well as mortgage, auto, and credit card delinquencies
were in the bottom range of the levels observed over
the past 20years. Household credit growth has been
almost exclusively among prime-rated borrowers,
including for residential mortgages. Nonetheless,
some households remained  nancially strained and
vulnerable to adverse shocks during this period of
heightened uncertainty.
Vulnerabilities from  nancial-sector leverage are
well within their historical range. Risk-based capital
ratios at domestic bank holding companies declined
some in the  rst quarter of 2022 but remained well
above regulatory requirements. Banks increased loan
loss provisions to re ect higher uncertainty about
the economic outlook and continued to report that
rising interest rates will support their pro tability
going forward. However, higher interest rates cause
losses in the market value of banks’ long-term  xed-
rate assets. Leverage remained high at life insurance
companies and was likely somewhat elevated at hedge
funds, though the most comprehensive data for hedge
funds are considerably lagged. Vulnerabilities of most
U.S.  nancial institutions to the Russian invasion of
Ukraine appear to be limited. Some nonbank  nancial
intermediaries—such as commodity trading  rms—
Developments Related to Financial Stability (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 33
in ation and greater-than-expected increases in interest
rates could negatively affect domestic economic
activity, asset prices, credit quality, and  nancial
conditions more generally. As concerns over cyber risk
have increased, U.S. government agencies and their
private-sector partners have been stepping up their
efforts to protect the  nancial system and other critical
infrastructures. These risks, if realized, could interact
with  nancial vulnerabilities and pose additional risks
to the U.S.  nancial system.
Invasion of Ukraine and Commodity Markets
Russia’s invasion of Ukraine and subsequent
international sanctions disrupted global trade in
commodities, leading to surging prices and heightened
volatility in agriculture, energy, and metals markets.
These markets include spot and forward markets for
physical commodities as well as futures, options,
and swaps markets that involve an array of  nancial
intermediaries and infrastructures. Stresses in  nancial
markets linked to commodities could disrupt the
ef cient production, processing, and transportation
of commodities by interfering with the ability of
commodity producers, consumers, and traders to
hedge risks. Such stresses can also increase liquidity
and credit risks for  nancial institutions that are active
in commodity markets. To date, however,  nancial
market stresses do not appear to have exacerbated
the negative effects on broader economic activity
or created substantial pressure on key  nancial
intermediaries, including banks. Since the invasion, for
most commodities, futures trading volumes and open
interest—the number of contracts outstanding at the
end of the day—have remained in normal ranges.
been able to meet these margin calls, and, in general,
CCPs effectively managed the increased risks and
higher trading volumes.
The aggregate value of stablecoins—digital assets
that aim to maintain a stable value relative to a
national currency or other reference assets—grew
rapidly over the past year to more than $180billion
in March2022. The stablecoin sector remained highly
concentrated, with the three largest stablecoin issuers—
Tether, USD Coin, and Binance USD—constituting
more than 80percent of the total market value.
The collapse in the value of certain stablecoins and
recent strains experienced in markets for other digital
assets demonstrate the fragility of such structures.
More generally, stablecoins that are not backed by
safe and suf ciently liquid assets and are not subject
to appropriate regulatory standards create risks to
investors and potentially to the  nancial system,
including susceptibility to potentially destabilizing runs.
These vulnerabilities may be exacerbated by a lack of
transparency regarding the riskiness and liquidity of
assets backing stablecoins. In addition, the increasing
use of stablecoins to meet margin requirements for
levered trading in other cryptocurrencies may amplify
volatility in demand for stablecoins and heighten
redemption risks. The President’s Working Group
on Financial Markets, the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation, and the Of ce of the Comptroller of the
Currency have made recommendations to address
prudential risks posed by stablecoins.
A routine survey of market contacts on salient
shocks to  nancial stability highlights several important
risks. Stresses in Europe related to Russia’s invasion of
Ukraine or in emerging markets could spill over to the
United States. In addition, higher or more persistent
34 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
55
60
65
70
75
80
Percent
2022202020182016201420122010200820062004
38. Ratio of total commercial bank credit to nominal
gross domestic product
Quarterly
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.8, “Assets and
Liabilities of Commercial Banks in the United States”; Bureau o
f
Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
at low levels since then. Market depth based
on the S&P 500 futures is below pre-pandemic
levels and currently in the bottom decile of its
historical distribution since 2018.
Short-term funding market conditions
remained stable . . .
Conditions in money markets have been stable
and orderly. Increases in the target range for
the federal funds rate fully passed through to
market overnight rates. The eective federal
funds rate and other unsecured overnight
rates have been a few basis points below the
interest rate on reserve balances since late
February. The Secured Overnight Financing
Rate has been at or below the oering rate at
the overnight reverse repurchase agreement
(ON RRP) facility, given ample liquidity and
a limited supply of Treasury bills. Softness
in repurchase agreement rates contributed to
ongoing increases in ON RRP take-up, which
reached an average of around $2.1trillion per
day in June. Russia’s invasion of Ukraine does
not appear to have left a material imprint in
the broad U.S. dollar funding markets to date.
In late February and early March, spreads
on some longer-tenor commercial paper and
negotiable certicates of deposit increased
notably amid uncertainties around monetary
policy tightening and Russia’s invasion of
Ukraine. These spreads have broadly narrowed
since mid-March.
Weighted average maturities for money market
funds (MMFs) stand at low levels, as MMFs
tend to adjust their portfolios toward shorter-
tenor instruments to position for rising interest
rates around monetary policy tighteningcycles.
Bank credit expanded in the rst quarter
amid strong loan demand
Strong loan growth pushed the ratio of bank
credit to GDP higher in the rst quarter
(gure38). The acceleration in growth was
broad based, with balance growth accelerating
for most major loan categories. Growth
was particularly strong for commercial and
industrial and credit card loans, for which
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 35
demand continued to strengthen in the rst
quarter according to the April2022 Senior
Loan Ocer Opinion Survey on Bank
Lending Practices. More recently, loan growth
moderated somewhat in May amid higher
rates and a more uncertain economic outlook
but remained strong. Bank protability also
remained strong but fell somewhat in the
rst quarter, in part as a result of declines
in investment banking revenue and the
fading boost to protability from the release
in previous quarters of loan loss reserves
accumulated in 2020 (gure39). Nevertheless,
higher interest rates and strong loan demand
are expected to support bank protability in
the near term. Delinquency rates on bank
loans remained low.
International Developments
Economic activity continued to recover
abroad . . .
Economic activity continued to recover in
many foreign economies in the rst quarter,
albeit at a slower pace than last year’s
strong performance. The still-robust growth
in many foreign economies reected the
recovery in many parts of the world from
previous pandemic shocks amid progress on
vaccinations and a greater ability to cope
with outbreaks without extensive lockdowns.
Moreover, unemployment rates in many
advanced foreign economies (AFEs) continued
to decline and are now below their pre-
pandemic levels (gure40).
More recently, headwinds from the war in
Ukraine and COVID-19 lockdowns in China
weighed on the foreign recovery. The slowing
of activity has been particularly sharp in
China, with recent indicators plunging amid
COVID-related mobility restrictions. In
Europe, recent indicators also show a sharp
slowing, reecting lower real incomes, reduced
condence of households and businesses in
the economy, and continued supply chain
disruptions.
Return on assets
30
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
Percent, annual rate
2.0
1.5
1.0
.5
+
_
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
39. Protability of bank holding companies
Percent, annual rate
Return on equity
N
OTE:The data are quarterly.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Form FR Y-9C, Consolidated
Financial Statements for Holding Companies.
United Kingdom
Canada
Japan 2
4
6
8
10
12
14
Percent
202220202018201620142012201020082006
40. Unemployment rate in selected advanced foreign
economies
Monthly
Euro area
N
OTE:The data for the United Kingdom extend through March 2022
and are centered 3-month averages of monthly data. The data for the
euro area and Japan extend through April 2022.
S
OURCE: For the United Kingdom, Oce for National Statistics; for
Japan, Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare; for the euro area,
Statistical Oce of the European Communities; for Canada, Statistics
Canada; all via Haver Analytics.
36 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
. . . while foreign ination remained on
the rise in most economies . . .
As in the United States, ination in many
foreign economies has continued to rise.
Soaring energy prices have remained a
major driver of higher ination in AFEs,
and rising food prices accounted for most of
the increase in ination in emerging market
economies (EMEs). Food and energy price
rises have made up the bulk of the increase,
though supply chain disruptions have
contributed as well, and inationary pressures
have broadened as elevated input costs are
increasingly passed through to prices of goods
and services. (See the box “Global Ination.”)
. . . and many foreign central banks are
tightening monetary policy
In response to elevated ination and
broadening price pressures, many AFE central
banks increased policy rates, and some started
to reduce the size of their balance sheets.
Concerns over the persistence of inationary
pressures led several EME central banks,
primarily those in Latin America, to raise
their policy rates further. Several central banks
in emerging Asia, where ination had been
more subdued but has recently begun to rise,
also started to raise policy rates. (See the box
“Monetary Policy in Foreign Economies.”)
Financial conditions abroad tightened
since the beginning of the year . . .
As central banks raised interest rates or
signaled that they would do so soon, market-
based policy expectations and sovereign
bond yields rose signicantly in many AFEs
(gure41). The rise in sovereign bond yields
reects increases in both real yields, arising
from less accommodative central bank
communications, and ination compensation.
Since the start of the year, short- and medium-
term ination compensation measures in
the euro area rose more than in many other
AFEs, reecting the region’s larger exposure
to the inationary pressures stemming from
Russia’s invasion of Ukraine. Sovereign bond
Germany
Canada
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent
2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
41. Nominal 10-year government bond yields in
selected advanced foreign economies
Weekly
United Kingdom
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily benchmark yields and
extend through June 10, 2022.
S
OURCE
: Bloomberg.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 37
Over the past year, in ation increased rapidly in
many foreign economies, re ecting soaring commodity
prices, pandemic-related supply disruptions, and
imbalances between demand for goods and services
( gure A). More recently, the war in Ukraine and the
renewals of COVID-19 lockdowns in China have
ampli ed in ationary pressures, particularly through
higher food and energy prices.
The recent surge in foreign in ation was mainly
concentrated in volatile components, such as food and
energy prices, with these components contributing
much more to in ation in recent months than in pre-
pandemic years ( gure B). In particular, energy prices
accounted for almost half of the 12-month headline
in ation rate for the advanced foreign economies (AFEs)
in April. Meanwhile, food prices are driving in ation
in emerging market economies, largely due to the war
and its threat to already fragile food security in these
economies.
Price pressures have recently broadened to core
in ation, as elevated input costs have been increasingly
passed through to prices of goods and services that
have not been directly affected by supply disruptions
and soaring commodity prices. This broadening
of in ationary pressure is re ected in increases in
the share of categories of core goods and services
prices rising more than 3percent in most major AFEs
( gureC). Furthermore, the rebalancing of demand
away from goods toward services—which would have
reduced upward pressures on prices of goods—has
been slower than expected so far, contributing to the
persistence of in ation pressures.
Persistent and widening price pressures are also
evident in increases in market- and survey-based
in ation expectations, although these expectations
generally remain anchored in historical ranges
( gureD). Even though such increases in in ation
expectations might be a welcome development for
economies such as Japan and the euro area that have
experienced persistently below-target in ation in
recent decades, many foreign central banks have been
tightening monetary policy amid broadened price
pressures and tight labor markets.
Global In ation
AFEs ex Japan
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
12-month percent change
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
A. Consumer price ination in foreign economies
Monthly
EMEs ex China
N
OTE: The advanced foreign economy (AFE) aggregate is the averag
e
of
Canada, the euro area, and the United Kingdom, weighted by
U.S.
goods
imports. The emerging market economy (EME) aggregate is
the
average
of Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia
,
Malaysia,
Mexico, Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, an
d
Thailand,
weighted by U.S. goods imports. The ination measure is
the
Harmonised
Index of Consumer Prices for the euro area and
the
consumer price index for other economies.
SOURCE:Haver Analytics.
(continued on next page)
38 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
United Kingdom
Euro area
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
Percent
2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
D. 5-to-10-year ination swaps
Daily
Japan
N
OTE: The euro-area and United Kingdom data have been
adjusted
using
an interpolated price index to mitigate rollover jumps a
t
month-ends.
The United Kingdom’s ination swaps are based on
the
retail
price index (RPI). RPI ination is, on average, 75 to 100 basi
s
points
higher than consumer price index ination. The data are at
a
business-day frequency.
SOURCE: Bloomberg; Haver Analytics; Federal Reserve Board s
taff
calculations.
United Kingdom
Euro area
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
Share of prices rising more than 3 percent
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
C.Diusion index for foreign core prices
Monthly
Canada
N
OTE: The data use the 12-month rise in prices. The prices of items a
re
weighted
according to their usual weights in the consumer price
index
and the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices. The data extend through
April 2022.
S
OURCE
:Haver Analytics; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Percent
2017–19 avg. April 2022
Advanced foreign economies ex Japan
B. Foreign consumer price ination components
Energy
Food
Core
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Percent
2017–19 avg. 2022:Q2
Emerging market economies ex China
Energy
Food
Core
NOTE: The advanced foreign economy (AFE) aggregate is the average of Canada, the euro area, and the United Kingdom, weighted by U.S. goods
imports. The emerging market economy (EME) aggregate is the average of Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Hong Kong, India, Israel,
Mexico,
Russia, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, South Korea, and the 5 original member countries of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations, weighted by
U.S.
goods imports. The ination measure is the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices for the euro area and the consumer price index f
or other economies.
The key identies bars in order from top to bottom. The data are 12-month percent changes for AFEs and 4-quarter percent changes for EMEs.
S
OURCE
: Haver Analytics.
Global In ation (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 39
With in ation rising sharply across the globe, central
banks have broadly shifted toward tighter monetary
policy. Policy tightening started last year, as some
emerging market central banks—particularly those in
Latin America—increased policy rates out of concern that
sharp increases in in ation could become entrenched
in in ation expectations. Among the advanced foreign
economies (AFEs), central banks of some smaller
economies (New Zealand and Norway) with particularly
strong recoveries were the  rst to hike their policy rates
last autumn, while policy expectations for some major
AFE central banks began to rise sharply ( gure A).
Last December, the Bank of England (BOE) raised
its policy rate from 0.1percent to 0.25percent, citing
a strong labor market and rising in ation. This year,
with U.K. in ation picking up more sharply, the BOE
followed with additional rate hikes in subsequent
meetings, taking its policy rate to 1percent in May. The
Bank of Canada (BOC) began raising its policy rate in
March with a 25 basis point hike. In response to sharply
higher in ation and the view that economic slack in
the Canadian economy had been absorbed, the BOC
followed with hikes of 50 basis points each in April
and June, bringing the policy rate to 1.5percent. As
in ation concerns grew more widespread, the Reserve
Bank of Australia (RBA) and the Swedish Riksbank
pivoted sharply to hike rates in May, and the European
Central Bank (ECB) recently stated that it intends to start
raising its policy rate in July.
Supporting the overall thrust toward tighter global
monetary policy, several AFE central banks that had
expanded their balance sheets over the past two years
are now allowing them to shrink. In recent months, the
BOE, the BOC, the RBA, and the Swedish Riksbank have
begun to shrink their balance sheets by stopping full
reinvestments of maturing government bond holdings.
The BOE has indicated that it will consider accelerating
the pace of balance sheet reduction by selling U.K.
government bonds; it will provide an update in
August on a strategy for possible future bond sales.
After tapering its purchases in recent months, the ECB
announced it will end net asset purchases as of July1.
Not all major foreign central banks have been
tightening monetary policy. The Bank of Japan (BOJ)
has maintained its overnight policy rate at negative
0.1percent, given its outlook that Japanese in ation
will remain subdued in the medium term. The BOJ also
vowed to continue purchasing Japanese government
bonds to defend its current yield curve control target
band around 0percent for the 10-year nominal yield. In
addition, the People’s Bank of China recently increased
its monetary stimulus through reductions in reserve
requirement ratios and some key benchmark interest
rates amid a weakening of economic activity in China.
Monetary Policy in Foreign Economies
Canada
Japan
Euro area
100
50
+
_
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
Basis points
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
A. 12-month policy expectations for selected advanced
foreign economies
Weekly
United Kingdom
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily 12-month
market-implied
central
bank policy rates. The 12-month policy rates are implied
by
quotes on overnight index swaps tied to the policy rates. The data extend
through June 10, 2022.
S
OURCE
: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board sta estimations.
40 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
spreads over German bund yields for euro-
area peripheral countries recently widened
signicantly. These moves partially retraced
following an unscheduled meeting of the
European Central Bank (ECB) on June15,
where the ECB indicated that it would take
action to address potential fragmentation in
euro-area sovereign bond markets.
Concerns about persistently high ination
and associated monetary policy tightening
across countries, as well as Russia’s invasion
of Ukraine and COVID lockdowns in
China, weighed on foreign risky asset prices
(gure42). Equities in many AFEs have
declined since the beginning of the year.
Equity declines were particularly strong in the
euro area, given the regions trade and nancial
linkages to Russia and concerns over the
possibility of the conict spreading to other
parts of Europe. Euro-area corporate bond
spreads have widened since the beginning of
the year and are well above their pre-pandemic
levels.
Financial conditions in EMEs have tightened
since the beginning of the year but are not
particularly tight relative to historical norms.
EME-dedicated funds have experienced
net outows so far this quarter, reversing
the inows in the rst quarter of this year
(gure43). Outows have been concentrated
in Asia, especially China. Since Russia’s
invasion of Ukraine, investment funds that
focus on emerging Europe have experienced
particularly rapid outows. EME sovereign
bond spreads widened considerably. European
emerging market equities and Chinese equities
declined signicantly, the latter amid COVID-
related lockdowns and related supply chain
constraints as well as continued regulatory
uncertainty. Latin American equities,
supported in part by rising commodity prices,
declined by less than other emerging markets.
75
50
25
+
_
0
25
50
75
100
Billions of dollars
202220202018201620142012
43. Emerging market mutual fund ows
NOTE: The bond and equity fund ows data are quarterly sums of weekly
data from December 29, 2011, to June 8, 2022. Weekly data span Thursday
through Wednesday, and the quarterly values are sums over weekly data for
weeks ending in that quarter. The fund ows data exclude funds located in
China.
SOURCE: EPFR Global.
Equity fund ows
Bond fund ows
Japan
Euro area
80
90
100
110
120
130
140
150
Week ending January 8, 2016 = 100
2016 2017 2018 2019202020212022
42. Equity indexes for selected foreign economies
Weekly
China
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend throug
h
June 10, 2022.
S
OURCE: For the euro area, Dow Jones Euro Stoxx Index; for Japan,
Tokyo Stock Price Index; for China, Shanghai Composite Index; all via
Bloomberg. (For Dow Jones Indices licensing information, see the note
on the Contents page.)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 41
. . . and the dollar appreciated notably
Since the beginning of the year, the broad
dollar index—a measure of the trade-weighted
value of the dollar against foreign currencies—
has risen notably amid safe-haven ows and
increases in U.S. yields (gure44). The dollar
appreciated more against AFE currencies
than EME currencies, as rising commodity
prices supported Latin American currencies.
The Chinese renminbi depreciated against the
dollar amid growth concerns related to the
lockdowns in China and weaker-than-expected
Chinese data releases. Among AFE currencies,
the dollar appreciated particularly strongly
against the Japanese yen, largely reecting the
widening U.S.–Japanese yield dierential.
EME dollar index
Broad dollar index
75
80
85
90
95
100
105
110
115
Week ending December 27, 2019 = 100
2014 2016 201820202022
44. U.S. dollar exchange rate indexes
Weekly
AFE dollar index
Dollar appreciation
N
OTE: The data, which are in foreign currency units per dollar, are
weekly averages of daily values of the broad dollar index, advanced
foreign economies (AFE) dollar index, and emerging market economies
(EME) dollar index. The weekly data extend through June 10, 2022. As
indicated by the leftmost arrow, increases in the data reect U.S. dollar
appreciation and decreases reect U.S. dollar depreciation.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.10, “Foreig
n
Exchange Rates.”
43
The Federal Open Market Committee
has swiftly raised the target range for the
federal funds rate and anticipates that
ongoing increases in the target range will
be appropriate
With ination far too high, well above the
Federal Open Market Committee’s (FOMC)
2percent objective, and with tight labor
market conditions, the Committee raised
the target range for the federal funds rate
o the eective lower bound in March. The
Committee continued to raise the target
range in May and June, bringing it to 1½to
1¾percent following the June meeting
(gure45). The Committee has also indicated
that it anticipates that ongoing increases in the
target range will be appropriate.
The Committee ceased net purchases of
Treasury securities and agency mortgage-
backed securities in early March and
began the process of signicantly
reducing its securities holdings on June1
Reecting the need to rm the stance of
monetary policy amid elevated ination and
tight labor market conditions, the Committee
ended net asset purchases in early March and
announced its plans for signicantly reducing
the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet
in May.
13
Consistent with the Principles for
Reducing the Size of the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet that were issued in January,
the May statement outlined the Committee’s
intention to reduce the Federal Reserve’s
securities holdings over time in a predictable
manner primarily by adjusting the amounts
reinvested of principal payments received from
securities held in the System Open Market
Account (SOMA).
14
Specically, beginning in
June, principal payments from securities held
in the SOMA will be reinvested to the extent
that they exceed monthly caps. For Treasury
securities, the cap is initially set at $30billion
per month and after three months will increase
13. See the May4, 2022, press release regarding the
Plans for Reducing the Size of the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet, available at https://www.federalreserve.
gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20220504b.htm.
14. See the January26, 2022, press release
regarding the Principles for Reducing the Size of the
Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet, available at https://
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/
monetary20220126c.htm.
Part 2
monetary PoLiCy
Target federal funds rate
2-year Treasury rate
0
1
2
3
4
5
Percent
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
45. Selected interest rates
Daily
10-year Treasury rate
N
OTE
: The 2-year and 10-year Treasury rates are the constant-maturity yields based on the most actively traded securities.
S
OURCE
: Department of the Treasury; Federal Reserve Board.
44 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
to $60billion per month. For agency debt and
agency mortgage-backed securities, the cap
is initially set at $17.5billion per month and
after three months will increase to $35billion
per month.
Reductions in securities holdings will slow and
then stop when reserve balances are somewhat
above the level the Committee judges to be
consistent with ecient implementation of
policy in an ample-reserves regime. Once
balance sheet runo has ceased, reserve
balances will likely continue to decline
at a slower pace—reecting growth in
other Federal Reserve liabilities—until the
Committee judges that reserve balances are
at the level required for implementing policy
eciently in an ample regime, at which point
reserve management purchases of securities
would likely begin to maintain ample reserves.
The Committee also noted that it is prepared
to adjust any of the details of its approach to
reducing the size of the balance sheet in light
of economic and nancial developments.
The FOMC will continue to monitor the
implications of incoming information for
the economic outlook
The Committee is strongly committed to
returning ination to its 2percent objective. In
assessing the appropriate stance of monetary
policy, the Committee will continue to monitor
the implications of incoming information
for the economic outlook. The Committee’s
assessments will take into account a wide
range of information, including readings on
ination and ination expectations, wages,
other measures of labor market conditions,
nancial and international developments, and
public health.
In addition to considering a wide range of
economic and nancial data and information
gathered from business contacts and other
informed parties around the country, such
as participants in conversations held as part
of the Fed Listens initiative, policymakers
routinely consult prescriptions for the policy
interest rate provided by various monetary
policy rules. These rule prescriptions can
provide useful benchmarks for the FOMC.
Although simple rules cannot capture the
complexities of monetary policy and many
practical considerations make it undesirable
for the FOMC to adhere strictly to the
prescriptions of any specic rule, some
principles of good monetary policy can
be illustrated by these policy rules (see the
box “Monetary Policy Rules in the Current
Environment”).
Changes to the policy rate were
implemented smoothly, and the size of
the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet was
roughly stable
As in the previous tightening cycle and
consistent with the implementation of
monetary policy in an ample-reserves regime,
the Federal Reserve used its administered
rates—the interest rate on reserve balances
(IORB) and the oering rate at the overnight
reverse repurchase agreement (ON RRP)
facility—to implement increases to the target
range for the policy rate. The administered
rates were eective in raising the eective
federal funds rate and other short-term interest
rates with the Committee’s target range.
The Federal Reserve’s balance sheet was
roughly stable at $9trillion, or 36percent
of U.S. nominal GDP, from February
through May, and the process to signicantly
reduce securities holdings began on June1
(gure46).
15
Reserve balances have fallen
from their all-time highs of a little over
$4trillion to around $3.3trillion because of
increasing take-up at the ON RRP. (See the
box “Developments in the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet and Money Markets.”)
15. Although balance sheet reduction started on
June1, the actual reduction in securities holdings has
been negligible thus far given the timing of principal
payments.
All of the Federal Reserve’s emergency credit and
liquidity facilities are closed and balances have continued
to decline as facilities’ assets mature or prepay. A list of
credit and liquidity facilities established by the Federal
Reserve in response to COVID-19 is available on the
Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.gov/
funding-credit-liquidity-and-loan-facilities.htm.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 45
10
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
10
Trillions of dollars
202220212020201920182017201620152014201320122011201020092008
46. Federal Reserve assets and liabilities
Weekly
Other assets
Credit and liquidity facilities
Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities holdings
Treasury securities held outright
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Deposits of depository institutions
Capital and other liabilities
N
OTE
: “Other assets” includes repurchase agreements, FIMA (Foreign and International Monetary Authorities) repurchase agreements, and
unamortized
premiums
and discounts on securities held outright. “Credit and liquidity facilities” consists of primary, secondary, and seasonal credit; term auction
credit;
central
bank liquidity swaps; support for Maiden Lane, Bear Stearns Companies, Inc., and AIG; and other credit and liquidity facilities, including
the
Primary
Dealer Credit Facility, the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility, the Commercial Paper
Funding
Facility,
the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility, the Primary and Secondary Market Corporate Credit Facilities, the Paycheck Protection
Program
Liquidity
Facility, the Municipal Liquidity Facility, and the Main Street Lending Program. “Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities holdings”
includes
agency
residential mortgage-backed securities and agency commercial mortgage-backed securities. “Capital and other liabilities” includes reverse r
epurchase
agreements, the U.S. Treasury General Account, and the U.S. Treasury Supplementary Financing Account. The key identies shaded
areas in order from top
to bottom. The data extend through June 8, 2022.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors Aecting Reserve Balances.”
46 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
gureA shows a “balanced-approach (shortfalls)”
rule, which represents one simple way to illustrate
the Committee’s focus on shortfalls from maximum
employment.
2
These rules embody key design
principles of good monetary policy, including that the
policy rate should be adjusted forcefully enough over
time to ensure a return of in ation to the central bank’s
longer-run objective and to anchor longer-term in ation
expectations at levels consistent with that objective.
All  ve rules feature the difference between in ation
and the FOMC’s longer-run objective of 2percent. The
ve rules use the unemployment rate gap, measured
as the difference between an estimate of the rate of
unemployment in the longer run (u
t
LR
) and the current
unemployment rate; the  rst-difference rule includes
the change in the unemployment rate gap rather than
its level.
3
All but the  rst-difference rule include an
rule is based on a rule suggested by Athanasios Orphanides
(2003), “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor
Rule,Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July), pp. 983–
1022. A review of policy rules is in John B. Taylor and John
C. Williams (2011), “Simple and Robust Rules for Monetary
Policy,” in Benjamin M. Friedman and Michael Woodford,
eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol.3B (Amsterdam:
North-Holland), pp. 829–59. The same volume of the
Handbook of Monetary Economics also discusses approaches
other than policy rules for deriving policy rate prescriptions.
2. The FOMC’s revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals
and Monetary Policy Strategy, released in August2020,
refers to “shortfalls of employment” from the Committee’s
assessment of its maximum level rather than the “deviations of
employment” used in the previous statement. The “balanced-
approach (shortfalls)” rule re ects this change by prescribing
policy rates identical to those prescribed by the balanced-
approach rule at times when the unemployment rate is
above its estimated longer-run level. However, when the
unemployment rate is below that level, the balanced-approach
(shortfalls) rule is more accommodative than the balanced-
approach rule because it does not call for the policy rate to
rise as the unemployment rate drops further.
3. Implementations of simple rules often use the output
gap as a measure of resource slack in the economy. The rules
described in gure A instead use the unemployment rate
gap because that gap better captures the FOMC’s statutory
goal to promote maximum employment. Movements in
these alternative measures of resource utilization are highly
correlated. For more information, see the note below gure A.
Simple interest rate rules relate a policy interest
rate, such as the federal funds rate, to a small number
of other economic variables—typically including the
current deviation of in ation from its target value
and a measure of resource slack in the economy.
Policymakers consult policy rate prescriptions derived
from a variety of policy rules as part of their monetary
policy deliberations without mechanically following the
prescriptions of any particular rule.
Recently, in ation has run well above the
Committee’s 2percent longer-run objective, the
U.S. economy has been very strong, and labor
market conditions have been very tight. Against
this background, the simple monetary policy rules
considered in this discussion have called for raising the
federal funds rate signi cantly. Starting in March, the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) began raising
the target range for the federal funds rate and indicated
that it anticipates that ongoing increases in the target
range will be appropriate. The FOMC also began the
process of signi cantly reducing the size of the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet.
Selected Policy Rules: Descriptions
In many economic models, desirable economic
outcomes can be achieved if monetary policy
responds in a predictable way to changes in economic
conditions. In recognition of this idea, economists
have analyzed many monetary policy rules, including
the well-known Taylor(1993) rule, the “balanced
approach” rule, the “adjusted Taylor(1993)” rule, and
the “ rst difference” rule.
1
In addition to these rules,
1. The Taylor(1993) rule was introduced in John B. Taylor
(1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-
Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol.39
(December), pp. 195–214. The balanced-approach rule was
analyzed in John B. Taylor (1999), “A Historical Analysis of
Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy
Rules (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 319–41. The
adjusted Taylor(1993) rule was studied in David Reifschneider
and John C. Williams (2000), “Three Lessons for Monetary
Policy in a Low-In ation Era,Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, vol. 32 (November), pp. 936–66. The  rst-difference
Monetary Policy Rules in the Current Environment
(continued)
n (u
t
LR
) a
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 47
gureA shows a “balanced-approach (shortfalls)”
rule, which represents one simple way to illustrate
the Committee’s focus on shortfalls from maximum
employment.
2
These rules embody key design
principles of good monetary policy, including that the
policy rate should be adjusted forcefully enough over
time to ensure a return of in ation to the central bank’s
longer-run objective and to anchor longer-term in ation
expectations at levels consistent with that objective.
All  ve rules feature the difference between in ation
and the FOMC’s longer-run objective of 2percent. The
ve rules use the unemployment rate gap, measured
as the difference between an estimate of the rate of
unemployment in the longer run (u
t
LR
) and the current
unemployment rate; the  rst-difference rule includes
the change in the unemployment rate gap rather than
its level.
3
All but the  rst-difference rule include an
rule is based on a rule suggested by Athanasios Orphanides
(2003), “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor
Rule,Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July), pp. 983–
1022. A review of policy rules is in John B. Taylor and John
C. Williams (2011), “Simple and Robust Rules for Monetary
Policy,” in Benjamin M. Friedman and Michael Woodford,
eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol.3B (Amsterdam:
North-Holland), pp. 829–59. The same volume of the
Handbook of Monetary Economics also discusses approaches
other than policy rules for deriving policy rate prescriptions.
2. The FOMC’s revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals
and Monetary Policy Strategy, released in August2020,
refers to “shortfalls of employment” from the Committee’s
assessment of its maximum level rather than the “deviations of
employment” used in the previous statement. The “balanced-
approach (shortfalls)” rule re ects this change by prescribing
policy rates identical to those prescribed by the balanced-
approach rule at times when the unemployment rate is
above its estimated longer-run level. However, when the
unemployment rate is below that level, the balanced-approach
(shortfalls) rule is more accommodative than the balanced-
approach rule because it does not call for the policy rate to
rise as the unemployment rate drops further.
3. Implementations of simple rules often use the output
gap as a measure of resource slack in the economy. The rules
described in gure A instead use the unemployment rate
gap because that gap better captures the FOMC’s statutory
goal to promote maximum employment. Movements in
these alternative measures of resource utilization are highly
correlated. For more information, see the note below gure A.
Simple interest rate rules relate a policy interest
rate, such as the federal funds rate, to a small number
of other economic variables—typically including the
current deviation of in ation from its target value
and a measure of resource slack in the economy.
Policymakers consult policy rate prescriptions derived
from a variety of policy rules as part of their monetary
policy deliberations without mechanically following the
prescriptions of any particular rule.
Recently, in ation has run well above the
Committee’s 2percent longer-run objective, the
U.S. economy has been very strong, and labor
market conditions have been very tight. Against
this background, the simple monetary policy rules
considered in this discussion have called for raising the
federal funds rate signi cantly. Starting in March, the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) began raising
the target range for the federal funds rate and indicated
that it anticipates that ongoing increases in the target
range will be appropriate. The FOMC also began the
process of signi cantly reducing the size of the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet.
Selected Policy Rules: Descriptions
In many economic models, desirable economic
outcomes can be achieved if monetary policy
responds in a predictable way to changes in economic
conditions. In recognition of this idea, economists
have analyzed many monetary policy rules, including
the well-known Taylor(1993) rule, the “balanced
approach” rule, the “adjusted Taylor(1993)” rule, and
the “ rst difference” rule.
1
In addition to these rules,
1. The Taylor(1993) rule was introduced in John B. Taylor
(1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-
Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol.39
(December), pp. 195–214. The balanced-approach rule was
analyzed in John B. Taylor (1999), “A Historical Analysis of
Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy
Rules (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 319–41. The
adjusted Taylor(1993) rule was studied in David Reifschneider
and John C. Williams (2000), “Three Lessons for Monetary
Policy in a Low-In ation Era,Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, vol. 32 (November), pp. 936–66. The  rst-difference
Monetary Policy Rules in the Current Environment
(continued)
n (u
t
LR
) a
Taylor(1993) rule prescribes delaying the return of the
policy rate to the (positive) levels prescribed by the
standard Taylor(1993) rule until after the economy
begins to recover.
Selected Policy Rules: Prescriptions
FigureB shows historical prescriptions for
the federal funds rate under the  ve simple rules
considered. For each quarterly period, the  gure reports
the policy rates prescribed by the rules, taking as given
the prevailing economic conditions and survey-based
estimates of u
t
LR
and r
t
LR
at the time. All of the rules
considered called for a highly accommodative stance
for monetary policy in response to the pandemic-
driven recession. The recent elevated in ation readings
imply that the prescriptions for the federal funds rate of
simple policy rules in the  rst quarter of 2022 are well
estimate of the neutral real interest rate in the longer
run (r
t
LR
).
4
Unlike the other simple rules featured here, the
adjusted Taylor(1993) rule recognizes that the federal
funds rate cannot be reduced materially below the
effective lower bound. To make up for the cumulative
shortfall in policy accommodation following a
recession during which the federal funds rate is
constrained by its effective lower bound, the adjusted
4. The neutral real interest rate in the longer run (
r
t
LR
) is
the level of the real federal funds rate that is expected to be
consistent, in the longer run, with maximum employment
and stable in ation. Like u
t
LR
, r
t
LR
is determined largely by
nonmonetary factors. The  rst-difference rule shown in
gureA does not require an estimate of r
t
LR
. However, this rule
has its own shortcomings. For example, research suggests that
this sort of rule often results in greater volatility in employment
and in ation relative to what would be obtained under the
Taylor(1993) and balanced-approach rules. (continued on next page)
A. Monetary policy rules
Balanced-approach rule
Balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule
First-dierence rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Adjusted Taylor (1993) rule
N: R
t
T93
, R
t
BA
, R
t
BAS
, R
t
T93adj
, and R
t
FD
represent the values of the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by the Taylor (1993),
balanc
ed-approach, balanced-approach (shortfalls), adjusted Taylor (1993), and rst-dierence rules, respectively.
R
t−1
denotes the midpoint of the target range for the federal funds rate for quarter t1, π
t
is the 4-quarter price ination for quarter t, u
t
is the
un
employment rate in quarter t, and r
t
LR
is the level of the neutral real federal funds rate in the longer run that is expected to be consistent with
sust
aining maximum employment and ination at the Federal Open Market Committee’s 2percent longer-run objective, represented by π
LR
.
In
addition, u
t
LR
is the rate of unemployment expected in the longer run. Z
t
is the cumulative sum of past deviations of the federal funds rate
fr
om the prescriptions of the Taylor (1993) rule when that rule prescribes setting the federal funds rate below an eective lower bound (ELB) of
12
.5 basis points.
The Taylor (1993) rule and other policy rules generally respond to the deviation of real output from its full capacity level. In these equations,
th
e output gap has been replaced with the gap between the rate of unemployment in the longer run and its actual level (using a relationship known
as
Okun’s law) to represent the rules in terms of the unemployment rate. The rules are implemented as responding to core personal consumption
ex
penditures (PCE) ination rather than to headline PCE ination because current and near-term core ination rates tend to outperform headline
in
ation rates as predictors of the medium-term behavior of headline ination.
R
t
T93
= r
t
LR
+ π
t
+ 0.5(π
t
π
LR
) + (u
t
LR
u
t
)
R
t
FD
= R
t−1
+ 0.5(π
t
π
LR
) + (u
t
LR
u
t
) − (u
t
L
R
4
u
t−4
)
R
t
T93adj
= max{R
t
T93
Z
t
,
ELB}
R
t
BAS
= r
t
LR
+ π
t
+ 0.5(π
t
π
LR
) + 2min{(u
t
LR
u
t
), 0}
R
t
BA
= r
t
LR
+ π
t
+ 0.5(π
t
π
LR
) + 2(u
t
LR
u
t
)
48 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
effective lower bound on interest rates, which limits
the extent to which the policy rate can be lowered to
support the economy. This constraint was particularly
evident in the aftermath of the pandemic-driven
recession, when the lower bound on the policy rate
motivated the FOMC’s other policy actions to support
the economy. Finally, simple policy rules generally
abstract from the risk-management considerations
associated with uncertainty about economic
relationships and the evolution of the economy. As
a result, the usefulness of simple policy rules can be
limited in unusual economic circumstances.
5
5. For example, Taylor(1993) on page 197 noted that
“there will be episodes where monetary policy will need to
be adjusted to deal with special factors. The Fed would need
more than a simple policy rule as a guide in such cases.
above their pre-pandemic levels, at between 4percent
and 7percent. Overall, the prescriptions of all simple
rules have risen notably over the past few quarters as
in ation readings climbed further above 2percent.
Policy Rules: Limitations
Simple policy rules are also subject to important
limitations. One important limitation is that simple
policy rules do not take into account the other tools of
monetary policy, such as large-scale asset purchases.
A second important limitation is that simple rules
respond to only a small set of economic variables and
thus necessarily abstract from many of the factors that
the FOMC considers when it assesses the appropriate
setting of the policy rate. Another limitation is that
most simple policy rules do not take into account the
Monetary Policy Rules in the Current Environment (continued)
First-dierence rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Balanced-approach rule
Federal funds rate
Balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule
18
15
12
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
6
9
Percent
20222021202020192018
B. Historical federal funds rate prescriptions from simple policy rules
Adjusted Taylor (1993) rule
N
OTE: The rules use historical values of core personal consumption expenditures ination, the unemployment rate, and, where applicable,
historical
values
of the midpoint of the target range for the federal funds rate. Quarterly projections of longer-run values for the federal funds rate and
the
unemployment
rate used in the computation of the rules’ prescriptions are derived through interpolations of biannual projections from Blue
Chip
Economic
Indicators. The longer-run value for ination is set to 2 percent. The rules data are quarterly, and the federal funds rate data are the
monthly
average of the daily midpoint of the target range for the federal funds rate.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Wolters Kluwer, Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 49
effective lower bound on interest rates, which limits
the extent to which the policy rate can be lowered to
support the economy. This constraint was particularly
evident in the aftermath of the pandemic-driven
recession, when the lower bound on the policy rate
motivated the FOMC’s other policy actions to support
the economy. Finally, simple policy rules generally
abstract from the risk-management considerations
associated with uncertainty about economic
relationships and the evolution of the economy. As
a result, the usefulness of simple policy rules can be
limited in unusual economic circumstances.
5
5. For example, Taylor(1993) on page 197 noted that
“there will be episodes where monetary policy will need to
be adjusted to deal with special factors. The Fed would need
more than a simple policy rule as a guide in such cases.
above their pre-pandemic levels, at between 4percent
and 7percent. Overall, the prescriptions of all simple
rules have risen notably over the past few quarters as
in ation readings climbed further above 2percent.
Policy Rules: Limitations
Simple policy rules are also subject to important
limitations. One important limitation is that simple
policy rules do not take into account the other tools of
monetary policy, such as large-scale asset purchases.
A second important limitation is that simple rules
respond to only a small set of economic variables and
thus necessarily abstract from many of the factors that
the FOMC considers when it assesses the appropriate
setting of the policy rate. Another limitation is that
most simple policy rules do not take into account the
Monetary Policy Rules in the Current Environment (continued)
First-dierence rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Balanced-approach rule
Federal funds rate
Balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule
18
15
12
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
6
9
Percent
20222021202020192018
B. Historical federal funds rate prescriptions from simple policy rules
Adjusted Taylor (1993) rule
N
OTE: The rules use historical values of core personal consumption expenditures ination, the unemployment rate, and, where applicable, historical
values of the midpoint of the target range for the federal funds rate. Quarterly projections of longer-run values for the federal funds rate and the
unemployment rate used in the computation of the rules’ prescriptions are derived through interpolations of biannual projections from Blue Chip
Economic Indicators. The longer-run value for ination is set to 2 percent. The rules data are quarterly, and the federal funds rate data are the monthly
average of the daily midpoint of the target range for the federal funds rate.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Wolters Kluwer, Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
With the Federal Reserve’s net asset purchases
concluding in March, the size of the balance sheet has
been roughly stable at $9 trillion since February2022
( gures A and B). At its May2022 meeting, the FOMC
announced plans for signi cantly reducing the size
of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet starting June1.
Balance sheet reduction, along with increases in the
target range for the federal funds rate,  rms the stance
of monetary policy.
Despite the roughly constant total size of the
balance sheet, reserves—the largest liability on the
Federal Reserve’s balance sheet—have continued to fall
signi cantly since February2022, re ecting growth in
take-up at the overnight reverse repurchase agreement
(ON RRP) facility ( gure C).
1
In addition, the Treasury
General Account (TGA)—another volatile liability—
rose considerably upon larger than expected tax
receipts and peaked just short of $1trillion on June2
before retracing the movement.
Usage at the ON RRP facility has risen $496 billion
since February2022 to stand at a record $2.2 trillion
at the time of this report. Low rates on repurchase
agreements—re ecting abundant liquidity in the
banking system and limited Treasury bill supply—have
contributed to this increasingly elevated participation.
1. Reserves consist of deposits held at Federal Reserve
Banks by depository institutions, such as commercial banks,
savings banks, credit unions, thrift institutions, and U.S.
branches and agencies of foreign banks. Reserve balances
allow depository institutions to facilitate daily payment
ows, both in ordinary times and in stress scenarios, without
borrowing funds or selling assets.
Developments in the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet and
Money Markets
A. Balance sheet comparison
Billions of dollars
June8,
2022
February16,
2022
Change
Assets
Total securities
Treasury securities 5,772 5,739 33
Agency debt and MBS 2,710 2,707 3
Net unamortized premiums 336 350 −14
Repurchase agreements 0 0 0
Loans and lending facilities
PPPLF 19 28 −8
Other loans and lending
facilities 37 40 −3
Central bank liquidity swaps 0 0 0
Other assets 47 48 −1
Total assets 8,921 8,911 10
Liabilities and capital
Federal Reserve notes 2,227 2,185 42
Reserves held by depository
institutions 3,317 3,797 −480
Reverse repurchase
agreements
Foreign o cial and
international accounts 272 257 14
Others 2,163 1,644 519
U.S. Treasury General
Account 627 709 −82
Other deposits 247 251 −5
Other liabilities and capital 69 67 1
Total liabilities and capital 8,921 8,911 10
Note: MBS is mortgage-backed securities. PPPLF is Paycheck Protection
Program Liquidity Facility. Components may not sum to totals because of
rounding.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors A ecting
Reserve Balances.
(continued on next page)
50 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
Trillions of dollars
2019 2020 2021 2022
C. Federal Reserve liabilities
Weekly
NOTE: “Capital and other liabilities” includes Treasury contributions. The key
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors Aecting
Reserve Balances.”
Reverse repurchase agreements
Deposits of depository institutions (reserves)
U.S. Treasury General Account
Other deposits
Capital and other liabilities
Federal Reserve notes
identies shaded areas in order from top to bottom. The data extend
through
June 8, 2022
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
Trillions of dollars
2019 2020 2021 2022
B. Federal Reserve assets
Weekly
N
OTE
: MBS is mortgage-backed securities. The key identies shaded areas in
order from top to bottom. The data extend through June 8, 2022.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors Aecting
Reserve Balances.”
Other assets
Loans
Central bank liquidity swaps
Repurchase agreements
Agency debt and MBS
Treasury securities
held outright
In addition, uncertainty about the magnitude and pace
of policy rate increases contributed to a preference
for short-duration assets, like those provided by the
ONRRP facility. The ON RRP facility is intended to
help keep the effective federal funds rate from falling
below the target range set by the FOMC, as institutions
with access to the ON RRP should be unwilling to lend
funds below the ON RRP’s pre-announced offering rate.
The facility continued to serve this intended purpose,
and the set of administered rates—interest on reserve
balances (IORB) and the ON RRP offering rate—was
effective at raising and maintaining the effective federal
funds rate within the target range during the policy rate
adjustments that have taken place since March.
Going forward, the planned balance sheet decline
will drain reserves from the banking system and add
longer-duration assets, which will likely put upward
pressure on short-term rates and reduce demand at
the ON RRP facility. The Committee will monitor the
evolution of reserves and other liabilities to ensure
a smooth entry into ef cient operation of monetary
policy in an ample-reserves regime.
Developments in the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet and Money Markets (continued)
51
In conjunction with the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) meeting held on
June14–15, 2022, meeting participants
submitted their projections of the most likely
outcomes for real gross domestic product
(GDP) growth, the unemployment rate, and
ination for each year from 2022 to 2024
and over the longer run. Each participant’s
projections were based on information
available at the time of the meeting, together
with her or his assessment of appropriate
monetary policy—including a path for the
federal funds rate and its longer-run value—
and assumptions about other factors likely
to aect economic outcomes. The longer-
run projections represent each participant’s
assessment of the value to which each variable
would be expected to converge, over time,
under appropriate monetary policy and in the
absence of further shocks to the economy.
Appropriate monetary policy” is dened as
the future path of policy that each participant
deems most likely to foster outcomes for
economic activity and ination that best
satisfy his or her individual interpretation of
the statutory mandate to promote maximum
employment and price stability.
Part 3
summary of eConomiC ProjeCtions
The following material was released after the conclusion of the June14–15, 2022, meeting of the
Federal Open Market Committee.
Table 1. Economic projections of Federal Reserve Board members and Federal Reserve Bank presidents, under their
individual assumptions of projected appropriate monetary policy, June 2022
Percent
Variable
Median
1
Central tendency
2
Range
3
2022 2023 2024
Longer
run
2022 2023 2024
Longer
run
2022 2023 2024
Longer
run
Change in real GDP
.....
1.7 1.7 1.9 1.8 1.5–1.9 1.3–2.0 1.5–2.0 1.8–2.0 1.0–2.0 0.8–2.5
1.0–2.2
1.6–2.2
March projection ..... 2.8 2.2 2.0 1.8 2.5–3.0 2.1–2.5 1.8–2.0 1.8–2.0 2.1–3.3 2.0–2.9 1.5–2.5 1.6–2.2
Unemployment rate
.....
3.7 3.9 4.1 4.0 3.6–3.8 3.8–4.1 3.9–4.1 3.5–4.2 3.2–4.0 3.2–4.5
3.2–4.3
3.5–4.3
March projection ..... 3.5 3.5 3.6 4.0 3.4–3.6 3.3–3.6 3.2–3.7 3.5–4.2 3.1–4.0 3.1–4.0 3.1–4.0 3.5–4.3
PCE ination
..........
5.2 2.6 2.2 2.0 5.0–5.3 2.4–3.0 2.0–2.5 2.0 4.8–6.2 2.3–4.0
2.0–3.0
2.0
March projection ..... 4.3 2.7 2.3 2.0 4.1–4.7 2.3–3.0 2.1–2.4 2.0 3.7–5.5 2.2–3.5 2.0–3.0 2.0
Core PCE ination
4
.....
4.3 2.7 2.3 4.2–4.5 2.5–3.2 2.1–2.5 4.1–5.0 2.5–3.5
2.0–2.8
March projection .....
4.1 2.6 2.3 3.9–4.4 2.4–3.0 2.1–2.4
3.6–4.5 2.1–3.5
2.0–3.0
Memo: Projected
appropriate policy path
Federal funds rate
......
March projection .....
3.4
1.9
3.8
2.8
3.4
2.8
2.5
2.4
3.1–3.6
1.6–2.4
3.6–4.1
2.4–3.1
2.9–3.6
2.4–3.4
2.3–2.5
2.3–2.5
3.1–3.9
1.4–3.1
2.9–4.4
2.1–3.6
2.1–4.1
2.1–3.6
2.0–3.0
2.0–3.0
N: Projections of change in real gross domestic product (GDP) and projections for both measures of ination are percent changes from the fourth quarter of the previous year to
the fourth quarter of the year indicated. PCE ination and core PCE ination are the percentage rates of change in, respectively, the price index for personal consumption expenditures
(PCE) and the price index for PCE excluding food and energy. Projections for the unemployment rate are for the average civilian unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of the year
indicated. Each participant’s projections are based on his or her assessment of appropriate monetary policy. Longer-run projections represent each participant’s assessment of the rate
to which each variable would be expected to converge under appropriate monetary policy and in the absence of further shocks to the economy. The projections for the federal funds
rate are the value of the midpoint of the projected appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the projected appropriate target level for the federal funds rate at the end of the
specied calendar year or over the longer run. The March projections were made in conjunction with the meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on March15–16, 2022. One
participant did not submit longer-run projections for the change in real GDP, the unemployment rate, or the federal funds rate in conjunction with the March15–16, 2022, meeting, and
one participant did not submit such projections in conjunction with the June14–15, 2022, meeting.
1. For each period, the median is the middle projection when the projections are arranged from lowest to highest. When the number of projections is even, the median is the average
of the two middle projections.
2. The central tendency excludes the three highest and three lowest projections for each variable in each year.
3. The range for a variable in a given year includes all participants’ projections, from lowest to highest, for that variable in that year
4. Longer-run projections for core PCE ination are not collected.
52 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
−3
−2
−1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Median of projections
Central tendency of projections
Range of projections
Actual
Percent
Change in real GDP
Longer
run
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Percent
Unemployment rate
Longer
run
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Percent
PCE inflation
Longer
run
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Percent
Core PCE inflation
Longer
run
Figure 1. Medians, central tendencies, and ranges of economic projections, 2022–24 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1. The data for the actual values of the
variables are annual.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 53
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
2022 2023 2024
Longer run
Percent
Figure 2. FOMC participants’ assessments of appropriate monetary policy: Midpoint of target range or target
level for the federal funds rate
N: Each shaded circle indicates the value (rounded to the nearest 1/8 percentage point) of an individual participant’s
judgment of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the appropriate target level for the
federal funds rate at the end of the specied calendar year or over the longer run. One participant did not submit
longer-run projections for the federal funds rate.
54 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
0.6−
0.7
0.8−
0.9
1.0−
1.1
1.2−
1.3
1.4−
1.5
1.6−
1.7
1.8−
1.9
2.0−
2.1
2.2−
2.3
2.4−
2.5
2.6−
2.7
2.8−
2.9
3.0−
3.1
3.2−
3.3
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
0.6−
0.7
0.8−
0.9
1.0−
1.1
1.2−
1.3
1.4−
1.5
1.6−
1.7
1.8−
1.9
2.0−
2.1
2.2−
2.3
2.4−
2.5
2.6−
2.7
2.8−
2.9
3.0−
3.1
3.2−
3.3
Percent range
Number of participants
2023
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
0.6−
0.7
0.8−
0.9
1.0−
1.1
1.2−
1.3
1.4−
1.5
1.6−
1.7
1.8−
1.9
2.0−
2.1
2.2−
2.3
2.4−
2.5
2.6−
2.7
2.8−
2.9
3.0−
3.1
3.2−
3.3
Percent range
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
0.6−
0.7
0.8−
0.9
1.0−
1.1
1.2−
1.3
1.4−
1.5
1.6−
1.7
1.8−
1.9
2.0−
2.1
2.2−
2.3
2.4−
2.5
2.6−
2.7
2.8−
2.9
3.0−
3.1
3.2−
3.3
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
Figure 3.A. Distribution of participants’ projections for the change in real GDP, 2022–24 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 55
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.0−
3.1
3.2−
3.3
3.4−
3.5
3.6−
3.7
3.8−
3.9
4.0−
4.1
4.2−
4.3
4.4−
4.5
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.0−
3.1
3.2−
3.3
3.4−
3.5
3.6−
3.7
3.8−
3.9
4.0−
4.1
4.2−
4.3
4.4−
4.5
Percent range
Number of participants
2023
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.0−
3.1
3.2−
3.3
3.4−
3.5
3.6−
3.7
3.8−
3.9
4.0−
4.1
4.2−
4.3
4.4−
4.5
Percent range
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2.8−
2.9
3.0−
3.1
3.2−
3.3
3.4−
3.5
3.6−
3.7
3.8−
3.9
4.0−
4.1
4.2−
4.3
4.4−
4.5
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
Figure 3.B. Distribution of participants’ projections for the unemployment rate, 2022–24 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
56 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
3.3−
3.4
3.5−
3.6
3.7−
3.8
3.9−
4.0
4.1−
4.2
4.3−
4.4
4.5−
4.6
4.7−
4.8
4.9−
5.0
5.1−
5.2
5.3−
5.4
5.5−
5.6
5.7−
5.8
5.9−
6.0
6.1−
6.2
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
3.3−
3.4
3.5−
3.6
3.7−
3.8
3.9−
4.0
4.1−
4.2
4.3−
4.4
4.5−
4.6
4.7−
4.8
4.9−
5.0
5.1−
5.2
5.3−
5.4
5.5−
5.6
5.7−
5.8
5.9−
6.0
6.1−
6.2
Percent range
Number of participants
2023
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
3.3−
3.4
3.5−
3.6
3.7−
3.8
3.9−
4.0
4.1−
4.2
4.3−
4.4
4.5−
4.6
4.7−
4.8
4.9−
5.0
5.1−
5.2
5.3−
5.4
5.5−
5.6
5.7−
5.8
5.9−
6.0
6.1−
6.2
Percent range
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
3.3−
3.4
3.5−
3.6
3.7−
3.8
3.9−
4.0
4.1−
4.2
4.3−
4.4
4.5−
4.6
4.7−
4.8
4.9−
5.0
5.1−
5.2
5.3−
5.4
5.5−
5.6
5.7−
5.8
5.9−
6.0
6.1−
6.2
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
Figure 3.C. Distribution of participants’ projections for PCE ination, 2022–24 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 57
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
3.3−
3.4
3.5−
3.6
3.7−
3.8
3.9−
4.0
4.1−
4.2
4.3−
4.4
4.5−
4.6
4.7−
4.8
4.9−
5.0
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
3.3−
3.4
3.5−
3.6
3.7−
3.8
3.9−
4.0
4.1−
4.2
4.3−
4.4
4.5−
4.6
4.7−
4.8
4.9−
5.0
Percent range
Number of participants
2023
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
3.3−
3.4
3.5−
3.6
3.7−
3.8
3.9−
4.0
4.1−
4.2
4.3−
4.4
4.5−
4.6
4.7−
4.8
4.9−
5.0
Percent range
Number of participants
2024
Figure 3.D. Distribution of participants’ projections for core PCE ination, 2022–24
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
58 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
3.13−
3.37
3.38−
3.62
3.63−
3.87
3.88−
4.12
4.13−
4.37
4.38−
4.62
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2022
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
3.13−
3.37
3.38−
3.62
3.63−
3.87
3.88−
4.12
4.13−
4.37
4.38−
4.62
Percent range
Number of participants
2023
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
3.13−
3.37
3.38−
3.62
3.63−
3.87
3.88−
4.12
4.13−
4.37
4.38−
4.62
Percent range
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.38−
1.62
1.63−
1.87
1.88−
2.12
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
3.13−
3.37
3.38−
3.62
3.63−
3.87
3.88−
4.12
4.13−
4.37
4.38−
4.62
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
Figure 3.E. Distribution of participants’ judgments of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the
federal funds rate or the appropriate target level for the federal funds rate, 2022–24 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 59
−3
−2
−1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Median of projections
70% confidence interval
Actual
Percent
Change in real GDP
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Lower Broadly
similar
Higher
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Uncertainty about GDP growth
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Risks to GDP growth
Median projection and condenceinterval basedon historical forecast errors
FOMC participants’ assessments of uncertainty and risks around their economicprojections
Figure 4.A. Uncertainty and risks in projections of GDP growth
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the
percent change in real gross domestic product (GDP) from the fourth quarter of the previous year to the fourth quarter of
the year indicated. The condence interval around the median projected values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on
root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more information
about these data is available in table 2. Because current conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over
the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors
may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections; these
current assessments are summarized in the lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty about
their projections as “broadly similar” to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the condence
interval shown in the historical fan chart as largely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their
projections. Likewise, participants who judge the risks to their projections as “broadly balanced” would view the
condence interval around their projections as approximately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in
economic projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
60 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Median of projections
70% confidence interval
Actual
Percent
Unemployment rate
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Lower Broadly
similar
Higher
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Uncertainty about the unemployment rate
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Risks to the unemployment rate
Median projection and condenceinterval based on historical forecast errors
FOMC participants’ assessments of uncertainty and risks around their economicprojections
Figure 4.B. Uncertainty and risks in projections of the unemployment rate
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the
average civilian unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of the year indicated. The condence interval around the median
projected values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government
forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more information about these data is available in table 2. Because current
conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the
condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current
assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections; these current assessments are summarized in the lower
panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty about their projections as “broadly similar” to the
average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the condence interval shown in the historical fan chart as
largely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their projections. Likewise, participants who judge the
risks to their projections as “broadly balanced” would view the condence interval around their projections as approxi-
mately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 61
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2017 2018 2019 20202021202220232024
Median of projections
70% confidence interval
Actual
Percent
PCE inflation
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Lower Broadly
similar
Higher
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Uncertainty about PCE inflation
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Risks to PCE inflation
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Lower Broadly
similar
Higher
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Uncertainty about core PCE inflation
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Risks to core PCE inflation
Median projection and condenceinterval basedon historical forecast errors
FOMC participants’ assessments of uncertaintyand risks around their economicprojections
Figure 4.C. Uncertainty and risks in projections of PCE ination
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the
percent change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) from the fourth quarter of the previous
year to the fourth quarter of the year indicated. The condence interval around the median projected values is assumed to
be symmetric and is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts made over the
previous 20 years; more information about these data is available in table 2. Because current conditions may dier from
those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on
the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and
risks around their projections; these current assessments are summarized in the lower panels. Generally speaking,
participants who judge the uncertainty about their projections as “broadly similar” to the average levels of the past 20
years would view the width of the condence interval shown in the historical fan chart as largely consistent with their
assessments of the uncertainty about their projections. Likewise, participants who judge the risks to their projections as
“broadly balanced” would view the condence interval around their projections as approximately symmetric. For
denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
62 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 20182019202020212022
Diffusion index
Change in real GDP
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 20182019202020212022
Diffusion index
Unemployment rate
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 20182019202020212022
Diffusion index
PCE inflation
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 20182019202020212022
Diffusion index
Core PCE inflation
Figure 4.D. Diusion indexes of participants’ uncertainty assessments
N: For each SEP, participants provided responses to the question “Please indicate your judgment of the uncertainty
attached to your projections relative to the levels of uncertainty over the past 20 years.” Each point in the diusion indexes
represents the number of participants who responded “Higher” minus the number who responded “Lower,” divided by the
total number of participants. Figure excludes March 2020 when no projections were submitted.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 63
Figure 4.E. Diusion indexes of participants’ risk weightings
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
Diffusion index
Change in real GDP
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
Diffusion index
Unemployment rate
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
Diffusion index
PCE inflation
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
Diffusion index
Core PCE inflation
N: For each SEP, participants provided responses to the question “Please indicate your judgment of the risk
weighting around your projections.” Each point in the diusion indexes represents the number of participants who
responded “Weighted to the Upside” minus the number who responded “Weighted to the Downside,” divided by the total
number of participants. Figure excludes March 2020 when no projections were submitted.
64 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Midpoint of target range
Median of projections
70% confidence interval*
Actual
Percent
Federal funds rate
Figure 5. Uncertainty and risks in projections of the federal funds rate
N: The blue and red lines are based on actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the Committee’s
target for the federal funds rate at the end of the year indicated. The actual values are the midpoint of the target range; the
median projected values are based on either the midpoint of the target range or the target level. The condence interval
around the median projected values is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts
made over the previous 20 years. The condence interval is not strictly consistent with the projections for the federal funds
rate, primarily because these projections are not forecasts of the likeliest outcomes for the federal funds rate, but rather
projections of participants’ individual assessments of appropriate monetary policy. Still, historical forecast errors provide
a broad sense of the uncertainty around the future path of the federal funds rate generated by the uncertainty about the
macroeconomic variables as well as additional adjustments to monetary policy that may be appropriate to oset the eects
of shocks to the economy.
The condence interval is assumed to be symmetric except when it is truncated at zero - the bottom of the lowest target
range for the federal funds rate that has been adopted in the past by the Committee. This truncation would not be intended
to indicate the likelihood of the use of negative interest rates to provide additional monetary policy accommodation if
doing so was judged appropriate. In such situations, the Committee could also employ other tools, including forward
guidance and large-scale asset purchases, to provide additional accommodation. Because current conditions may dier
from those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated
on the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and
risks around their projections.
* The condence interval is derived from forecasts of the average level of short-term interest rates in the fourth quarter
of the year indicated; more information about these data is available in table 2. The shaded area encompasses less than a
70 percent condence interval if the condence interval has been truncated at zero.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 65
Table 2. Average historical projection error ranges
Percentage points
Variable 2022 2023 2024
Change in real GDP
1
......... ± 1.5 ± 1.9 ± 2.3
Unemployment rate
1
......... ± 0.8 ± 1.4 ± 1.9
Total consumer prices
2
....... ± 1.0 ± 1.3 ± 1.4
Short-term interest rates
3
..... ± 0.6 ± 1.8 ± 2.3
N: Error ranges shown are measured as plus or minus the root mean squared
error of projections for 2002 through 2021 that were released in the summer by
various private and government forecasters. As described in the box “Forecast
Uncertainty,” under certain assumptions, there is about a 70percent probability that
actual outcomes for real GDP, unemployment, consumer prices, and the federal funds
rate will be in ranges implied by the average size of projection errors made in the past.
For more information, see David Reifschneider and Peter Tulip (2017), “Gauging
the Uncertainty of the Economic Outlook Using Historical Forecasting Errors: The
Federal Reserve’s Approach,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2017-020
(Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February), https://
dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2017.020.
1. Denitions of variables are in the general note to table1.
2. Measure is the overall consumer price index, the price measure that has been
most widely used in government and private economic forecasts. Projections are
percent changes on a fourth quarter to fourth quarter basis.
3. For Federal Reserve sta forecasts, measure is the federal funds rate. For
other forecasts, measure is the rate on 3-month Treasury bills. Projection errors are
calculated using average levels, in percent, in the fourth quarter.
66 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
reported in table2 would imply a probability of about
70percent that actual GDP would expand within a
range of 1.5 to 4.5percent in the current year, 1.1 to
4.9percent in the second year, and 0.7 to 5.3percent
in the third year. The corresponding 70percent
con dence intervals for overall in ation would be 1.0
to 3.0percent in the current year, 0.7 to 3.3percent
in the second year, and 0.6 to 3.4percent in the third
year. Figures 4.A through 4.C illustrate these con dence
bounds in “fan charts” that are symmetric and centered
on the medians of FOMC participants’ projections for
GDP growth, the unemployment rate, and in ation.
However, in some instances, the risks around the
projections may not be symmetric. In particular, the
unemployment rate cannot be negative; furthermore,
the risks around a particular projection might be tilted
to either the upside or the downside, in which case
the corresponding fan chart would be asymmetrically
positioned around the median projection.
Because current conditions may differ from those
that prevailed, on average, over history, participants
provide judgments as to whether the uncertainty
attached to their projections of each economic variable
is greater than, smaller than, or broadly similar to
typical levels of forecast uncertainty seen in the past
20years, as presented in table2 and re ected in the
widths of the con dence intervals shown in the top
panels of  gures 4.A through 4.C. Participants’ current
assessments of the uncertainty surrounding their
projections are summarized in the bottom-left panels
The economic projections provided by the members
of the Board of Governors and the presidents of
the Federal Reserve Banks inform discussions of
monetary policy among policymakers and can aid
public understanding of the basis for policy actions.
Considerable uncertainty attends these projections,
however. The economic and statistical models and
relationships used to help produce economic forecasts
are necessarily imperfect descriptions of the real world,
and the future path of the economy can be affected
by myriad unforeseen developments and events. Thus,
in setting the stance of monetary policy, participants
consider not only what appears to be the most likely
economic outcome as embodied in their projections,
but also the range of alternative possibilities, the
likelihood of their occurring, and the potential costs to
the economy should they occur.
Table 2 summarizes the average historical accuracy
of a range of forecasts, including those reported in
past Monetary Policy Reports and those prepared
by the Federal Reserve Board’s staff in advance of
meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC). The projection error ranges shown in the
table illustrate the considerable uncertainty associated
with economic forecasts. For example, suppose a
participant projects that real gross domestic product
(GDP) and total consumer prices will rise steadily at
annual rates of, respectively, 3percent and 2percent.
If the uncertainty attending those projections is similar
to that experienced in the past and the risks around
the projections are broadly balanced, the numbers
Forecast Uncertainty
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JUNE 2022 67
on an end-of-year basis. However, the forecast errors
should provide a sense of the uncertainty around the
future path of the federal funds rate generated by the
uncertainty about the macroeconomic variables as
well as additional adjustments to monetary policy that
would be appropriate to offset the effects of shocks to
theeconomy.
If at some point in the future the con dence interval
around the federal funds rate were to extend below
zero, it would be truncated at zero for purposes of
the fan chart shown in  gure5; zero is the bottom of
the lowest target range for the federal funds rate that
has been adopted by the Committee in the past. This
approach to the construction of the federal funds rate
fan chart would be merely a convention; it would
not have any implications for possible future policy
decisions regarding the use of negative interest rates to
provide additional monetary policy accommodation
if doing so were appropriate. In such situations, the
Committee could also employ other tools, including
forward guidance and asset purchases, to provide
additional accommodation.
While  gures 4.A through 4.C provide information
on the uncertainty around the economic projections,
gure1 provides information on the range of views
across FOMC participants. A comparison of  gure1
with  gures 4.A through 4.C shows that the dispersion
of the projections across participants is much smaller
than the average forecast errors over the past 20years.
of those  gures. Participants also provide judgments as
to whether the risks to their projections are weighted
to the upside, are weighted to the downside, or
are broadly balanced. That is, while the symmetric
historical fan charts shown in the top panels of  gures
4.A through 4.C imply that the risks to participants’
projections are balanced, participants may judge that
there is a greater risk that a given variable will be above
rather than below their projections. These judgments
are summarized in the lower-right panels of  gures 4.A
through 4.C.
As with real activity and in ation, the outlook
for the future path of the federal funds rate is subject
to considerable uncertainty. This uncertainty arises
primarily because each participant’s assessment of
the appropriate stance of monetary policy depends
importantly on the evolution of real activity and
in ation over time. If economic conditions evolve
in an unexpected manner, then assessments of the
appropriate setting of the federal funds rate would
change from that point forward. The  nal line in
table2 shows the error ranges for forecasts of short-
term interest rates. They suggest that the historical
con dence intervals associated with projections
of the federal funds rate are quite wide. It should
be noted, however, that these con dence intervals
are not strictly consistent with the projections for
the federal funds rate, as these projections are not
forecasts of the most likely quarterly outcomes but
rather are projections of participants’ individual
assessments of appropriate monetary policy and are
69
AFE advanced foreign economy
BOC Bank of Canada
BOE Bank of England
BOJ Bank of Japan
CCP central counterparty
COVID-19 coronavirus disease 2019
CPI consumer price index
ECB European Central Bank
ECI employment cost index
EME emerging market economy
EPOP ratio employment-to-population ratio
FOMC Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee
GDP gross domestic product
IORB interest rate on reserve balances
LFPR labor force participation rate
MBS mortgage-backed securities
MMF money market fund
ON RRP overnight reverse repurchase agreement
PCE personal consumption expenditures
repo repurchase agreement
SOMA System Open Market Account
S&P Standard & Poor’s
TGA Treasury General Account
USD U.S. dollar
VIX implied volatility for the S&P 500 index
abbreviations
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m. EDT
June 17, 2022
Monetary Policy rePort
June 17, 2022